Dittmar 2010 - Quản trị kinh doanh | Trường Đại học Tài chính - Ngân hàng Hà Nội

Dittmar 2010 - Quản trị kinh doanh | Trường Đại học Tài chính - Ngân hàng Hà Nội được sưu tầm và soạn thảo dưới dạng file PDF để gửi tới các bạn sinh viên cùng tham khảo, ôn tập đầy đủ kiến thức, chuẩn bị cho các buổi học thật tốt. Mời bạn đọc đón xem!

Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
‘I want it and I want it now’: Using a temporal
discounting paradigm to examine predictors
of consumer impulsivity
Helga Dittmar* and Rod Bond
University of Sussex, Brighton, UK
This paper proposes a new model of consumer impulsivity, using type of good, a
person’s endorsement of materialistic values, and identity deficits as predictors.
Traditional decision making and psychological accounts see impulsive behaviour as a
general overweighing of short-term gratification (I want that dress now) relative to
longer-term concerns, irrespective of consumer good. Our proposal is that consumers’
impulsivity (a) differs according to type of good and (b) is linked systematically to a
combination of materialistic values and high identity deficits. Beginning with Study 1,
three experiments, using a temporal discounting paradigm, show consistently that
discount rates are higher for goods that are seen as highly expressive of identity (e.g.,
clothes) than goods not expressive of identity (e.g., basic body care products). For
materialistic consumers, identity deficits predict discount rates for identity-expressive
goods (Study 2), and discount rates change for materialistic individuals when their
identity deficits are made salient (Study 3). These findings support a conceptualization
of consumer impulsivity as identity-seeking behaviour.
Impulsivity can be described as ‘acting without thinking’, where people are more
motivated by immediate reward, rather than by long-term consequences of their
behaviour. This characteristic of everyday decision making also applies to wanting
particular consumer goods now, rather than planning consumption over time to
maximize long-term satisfaction. Consumers often experience conflict between desiring
particular goods right now, on the spur of the moment, and wanting to spend their
money sensibly on objects from which they can be sure to derive benefits over time.
When the short-term desire wins out, the consumer engages in impulse buying. In a
qualitative study, consumers defined impulse buying as ‘Just buying it, quickly, without
going away and thinking about it, buying it straight away’ or ‘Something I see and don’t
plan and I think “I’d like that”’ (Dittmar & Drury, 2000, pp. 123–124). In this paper,
we define consumer impulsivity as decisions about material goods that are characterized
by a strong, immediate desire for the good in question, lack of deliberation or planning,
* Correspondence should be addressed to Dr Helga Dittmar, School of Psychology, Pevensey 1, University of Sussex,
Brighton BN1 9QH, UK (e-mail: h.e.dittmar@sussex.ac.uk).
The
British
Psychological
Society
751
British Journal of Psychology (2010), 101, 751–776
q 2010 The British Psychological Society
www.bpsjournals.co.uk
DOI:10.1348/000712609X484658
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
and disregard for financial constraints (Baumeister, 2002; Dittmar, 2001; Verplanken &
Herabadi, 2001). We thus use the traditional definition of impulsivity that emphasizes
lack of forethought and deliberation (Ainslie, 1975; Martin & Potts, 2009), rather
than referring to impulsivity in terms of impatience (Frederick, Loewenstein, &
O’Donoghue, 2002).
Impulse buying is extremely common, with 90% of people making such purchases at
least occasionally (Hausmann, 2000), yet people often wish afterwards they had not
done so. In studies of impulse buyers, 80% were found to refer to some negative
consequences from their purchases (Rook, 1987), and 55% explicitly reported regret at
least once in a purchase diary (Dittmar, 2001). The near ubiquity combined with the
potential negative impact of this behaviour highlights the need for a better
understanding of factors that impact consumer impulsivity.
Individuals are not, however, impulsive all the time or with respect to all the
decisions they make, but this is something not well-explained by traditional
perspectives in decision making and microeconomics. We have no systematic
explanation of the fact that, typically, impulse purchases tend to be made for some
types of consumer goods, such as fashionable clothes, rather than others, such as basic
body care products (e.g., Dittmar, 2001).
We propose to examine three predictors of consumers’ impulsivity, all linked to
identity, defined as the subjective concept (or representation) that a person holds of
her- or himself (Vignoles, Regalia, Manzi, Golledge, & Scabini, 2006). The first
predictor is type of consumer good. People are typically more psychologically invested
in material goods that offer a high potential for the expression and communication
of identity than goods that are purely or mainly functional (Csikszentmihalyi &
Rochberg-Halton, 1981; Dittmar, 1992, 2008, in press; Kamptner, 1991). We therefore
propose that goods high in identity-expressive potential are discounted more steeply.
The next two predictors are linked. One of these predictors, materialistic values, can
be defined as a ‘set of centrally held beliefs about the importance of possessions in
one’s life’ (Richins & Dawson, 1992, p. 308). Those who endorse materialistic values
believe that acquiring new material goods is vital, particularly goods that are
expressive of social status, fame, and image (Dittmar, 2008; Kasser & Kanner, 2004).
Implicit in this type of materialism is the assumption that material goods are a good
way of attaining a better, more positive identity more status, more fame, and more
image which should make the buying of identity-expressive goods particularly
important to those who, in addition to endorsing materialistic values, also have high
identity deficits. Identity deficits, the other predictor, are defined as the salience of
perceived gaps between a person’s actual self (how they are) and their ideal self
(how they would ideally like to be).
We use an adaptation of the matching technique in a temporal discounting paradigm
(e.g., Benzion, Rapoport, & Yagil, 1989), because it provides a useful quantitative
measure of the extent to which an immediate reward is preferred to a larger, but delayed
reward. This paper reports three experimental studies which test the proposed new
consumer impulsivity model. In line with recent challenges to the discounted utility
model (Frederick et al., 2002), the first experiment focuses on systematic differences in
discounting as a function of type of consumer good. The second experiment examines
individuals’ materialistic value endorsement and identity deficits as additional predictors
of discount rates, and the third demonstrates that an experimental manipulation of
identity deficits in materialistic individuals affects discount rates for a good with high
identity-expressive potential.
752 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
‘I want it and I want it now’: Previous theoretical frameworks
Consumer impulsivity is characterized by an immediate, strong desire for a particular
good, by a lack of deliberation and careful planning, and often disregard for financial
constraints and consequences (Baumeister, 2002; Dittmar & Drury, 2000). There is a
battle between self-control on one hand, and desire on the other: ‘The budget is tight,
the price is too high, the item is not desperately needed, and so the shopper should not
buy it. Ranged against these sensible concerns is a murky alliance of wants, impulses,
and emotions, all clamoring for the gratification of the purchase’ (Baumeister, 2002,
p. 670). Our definition of consumer impulsivity is consistent with traditional
approaches to impulsivity (Ainslie, 1975; Martin & Potts, 2009).
Both anecdotal and research evidence suggests that consumer impulsivity is strong
with respect to certain types of goods, such as fashionable clothes and accessories,
but not with respect to others, such as basic body care products or tools (Dittmar &
Beattie, 1998; Dittmar, Beattie, & Friese, 1995, 1996), yet traditional accounts in
microeconomics and psychology
1
have tended to see consumer impulsivity as a general
overweighing of short-term gratification relative to longer-term concerns, irrespective of
consumer good.
Consumer impulsivity is a problem for traditional microeconomic decision theory
because it implies time-inconsistent preferences that switch from ‘I want it now’ to
later regret, violating the central assumption of the discounted utility model that
individuals have a consistent and unitary rate of time preference according to which
they discount the value of all delayed events. One influential variation conceptualizes
intertemporal choice as the outcome of a conflict between different selves: a ‘myopic’
doer focused on immediate gratification and a ‘farsighted’ planner concerned with long-
term benefits. Impulse buyers are assumed to discount the future at too rapid a rate,
where the benefits of the desired object at the point of imminent purchase outweigh
the (future) problem of paying the bill (e.g., Strotz, 1956; Winston, 1980). This does not
explain, however, why discounting should be disproportionately high, or why and
when people shift between short- and long-term preferences.
Ainslie (e.g., Ainslie, 1975, 1992, 2005) has challenged the traditional model. He
argues that delaying rewards from the moment of choice causes them to lose
effectiveness, so that preferences between a small-early and larger-late reward switch at
some point. Hence, discount rates are delay-dependent and follow a hyperbolic
function. Although he does not explicitly refer to differential discount rates for different
types of consumer goods, his hyperbolic discounting model leaves open that possibility.
Recent work, similarly, has challenged the assumption of a ‘unitary discount rate that
applies to all acts of consumption’ (Frederick et al., 2002, p. 394), and a series of
experiments consistently shows that consumables, such as food or drinks, are
discounted temporally more steeply than money (Estle, Green, Myerson, & Holt, 2007;
Odum, Baumann, & Rimington, 2006; Odum & Rainaud, 2003). However, we still know
little about psychological factors that impact temporal discounting of consumer goods
(i.e., variations in discounting that are likely to reflect psychological motives; Frederick
et al., 2002; Green & Myerson, 2004; Loewenstein, Read, & Baumeister, 2003).
1
Consumer behaviour and marketing work on impulse buying has been descriptive and a theoretical, identifying factors which
increase unplanned purchasing, such as exposure to in-store stimuli (e.g., Abratt & Goodey, 1990), or developing lists of foods
and drinks most likely to be bought impulsively (e.g., Bellenger, Robertson, & Hirschman, 1978). This does not explain
underlying motives, nor predict beyond the particular goods studied, thus not offering predictions regarding temporal
discounting.
Identity and consumers impulsivity 753
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Hoch and Loewenstein (1991) offer a reference point model where consumers imagine
themselves as owning the good before they actually purchase it, and hence experience
foregoing the purchase as a loss and therefore an additional cost. The probability of such
a ‘reference shift’ is affected by several factors, such as people’s evaluations of goods,
and hence impact impulsivity. In later work, Loewenstein (1996, 2000) focuses on
‘visceral’ influences that produce short-term increases in the attractiveness of certain
goods. Others have suggested that goods which are an investment, or which
complement an investment, may be discounted more steeply (Borghans, Duckworth,
Heckman, & ter Weel, 2008; Borghans & Goldsteyn, 2006). For example, if owning a
particular good helps people to study towards an important qualification, then that good
complements the investment in study, and will therefore have higher utility. However,
its utility in the future may not be clear to the individual since they cannot assess their
needs at that future date a ‘lack of imagination’. Therefore, a good may not have a fixed
utility, but its utility may vary across time depending on an assessment of how it meets
individual needs.
In our research, we focus on identity-related factors as a framework for
understanding characteristics of consumer goods and individual consumers that affect
temporal discounting. Identity, an individual’s subjective representation of her- or
himself (Vignoles et al., 2006), is multifaceted and, in addition to individual, relational,
and group levels of self-representation (Sedikides & Brewer, 2001), also includes
material goods as parts of individuals’ extended identity (Dittmar, 1992, in press). This
can be applied to within-individual variations, whereby individuals can be impulsive at
certain times, but not others, depending on whether goods are linked to identity or not,
and to between-individual variations, whereby some people are more impulsive than
others (i.e., those with stronger identity-related motives for material goods).
Traditionally, individual differences in impulsivity have been explained in terms
of impulse control and personality traits. The ability to delay gratification improves
with developmental stage (Mischel, Ayduk, & Mendoza-Denton, 2003), and can be
used as an individual difference variable to predict performance on certain cognitive
tasks (e.g., Baron, Badgio, & Gaskins, 1986). Supporting evidence shows that children
discount future rewards more steeply than young adults who, in turn, discount more
steeply than older adults (Green, Fry, & Myerson, 1994), suggesting that young people
commit more impulsive acts than do the elderly (Read & Read, 2004). Others have
conceptualized impulsivity as a stable personality trait and found that highly impulsive
individuals show higher discount rates than their less impulsive counterparts
(Ostaszewski, 1996). Verplanken and Herabadi (2001) showed that general impulse
buying tendency correlates negatively with conscientiousness and positively with
extraversion of the Big Five personality dimensions, as well as with arousal and hedonic
buying considerations (Herabadi, Verplanken, & van Knippenberg, 2009). Baumeister
and colleagues (Baumeister, 2002; Baumeister & Vohs, 2003; Baumeister, Vohs, & Tice,
2008) see individual differences in self-control failure as a powerful potential predictor
of impulsive purchasing. Hence, the common implication is that there are stable
individual differences in impulsivity which, presumably, should manifest themselves
across different types of consumer goods, in the sense that individuals who discount
more steeply than others for one type of consumer good, should also discount more
steeply for other types of goods.
These frameworks, however, need further development. None offers an account of
one of the most striking aspects of consumer impulsivity: why it is the case that certain
goods tend to be bought impulsively (such as fashionable clothes) whereas others
754 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
commonly are not (such as basic body care products). The traditional discounted utility
model would predict that temporal discounting is independent of type of consumer
good. Trait-based approaches predict stable individual differences in discounting: if
some people are more impulsive than others, then this general propensity should
manifest itself across consumer goods. In contrast, we propose a new model with three
identity-related predictors of consumer impulsivity.
A new model of consumer impulsivity
Our starting-point is that consumer impulsivity in well-developed mass consumer
societies such as the UK has to be understood in the context of the contemporary
sociocultural environment. An increasingly powerful context in which individuals
construct and express their identities is the material and consumer culture we live in.
Having the ‘right’ material goods has become vital to many, not so much because of these
things themselves, but because of hoped for psychological benefits, such as moving
closer to an ideal identity, creating a desired social image, and achieving positive
emotional states. One reason for this greater psychological significance of material goods
is that traditional, stable means of identity construction such as community, class,
religion, family, or nationality have become eroded, particularly in urban
environments, leading to an empty self (Cushman, 1990). Instead of being ascribed
by the kinds of contextual factors listed above, identity is increasingly byachieved
the individual her- or himself. An important element of such achieved identity is
the acquisition, ownership, and consumption of material goods, which are used
increasingly to symbolize to self and others who a person is, their actual self, and who
they would like to be, their ideal self (Dittmar, 2000, 2004a,b, 2008, in press). Our model
includes three identity-related factors that we test as predictors of consumer impulsivity.
Types of consumer goods
We propose that goods which have high identity-expressive potential are more likely to
be bought on impulse than goods unlikely to serve in this fashion. Extensive qualitative
research, using a ‘favourite possessions paradigm’, analyses the reasons why people
treasure some of their material goods very highly (Csikszentmihalyi & Rochberg-Halton,
1981; Dittmar, 1989, 1992, 2008, in press; Kamptner, 1991). In these accounts, it
emerges that identity construction, expression, and maintenance are powerful
psychological determinants of why material goods are important to people, with
clothes emerging as a particularly potent identity-expressive type of good. This is further
confirmed in analyses of clothes as consumer goods to be bought, as well as goods
already owned (Dittmar, 2008; Solomon, 1985). For example, in a UK community
sample, adults rated the importance of motives for buying clothes as compared to basic
body care products (such as shampoo) when they buy these types of goods on impulse,
defined as ‘a “spur of the moment” decision in the shop’. Buying motives to obtain
psychological benefits were all higher for clothes, such as improving one’s mood or
increasing one’s status, but the difference was most pronounced on the motives for
identity expression and moving closer to an ideal self (Dittmar, 2008, pp. 56–57).
Thus, clothes should make more likely targets for consumer impulsivity than goods
that have less identity-expressive potential, such as saucepans, and this has been
demonstrated in earlier studies, particularly for women (Dittmar et al., 1995). In support
of our proposal that material goods with high identity-expressive potential make more
Identity and consumers impulsivity 755
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
likely impulse buys than goods which do not offer such potential, we can draw on data
from our own previous research. In one study (Dittmar & Anderson, 2004), a sample
of adult employees rated different reasons why they buy and value four different
consumer goods. Means for the scale ‘express who you are, make you feel more like
your ideal’ are given in the first column of Table 1. We found that clothes have a much
stronger identity-expressive function than the other three types of goods, particularly
basic body care products and tools, with effect sizes ranging from .6 to .8.
At the same time, we have data from two previous studies on how frequently these
goods are actually bought on impulse. In a study with students (Dittmar et al., 1996), we
collected indices that compare the reported frequency of buying a type of good on
impulse with the frequency of buying it in a planned fashion, such that the resulting
index varies from 21 to þ1, with less negative numbers reflecting relatively greater
impulse buying. The means are given in the second column of Table 1 and show that
sports gear and clothes are types of good that, comparatively, are more likely to be
bought on impulse than basic body care products.
A third study demonstrates directly how often these types of goods are actually
bought on impulse. Respondents from a community sample completed ‘shopping
diaries’ for 1 month, recording all impulse purchases made (Dittmar, 2001, 2005b).
Clothes stood out as the single, most frequent impulse buy. Respondents bought clothes
significantly more often on impulse than basic body care items and music items (see the
last column in Table 1 for means). Taken together, the findings in the ‘favourite
possessions’ paradigm in conjunction with the data presented in Table 1 offer a sound
basis for concluding that clothes are a type of consumer good that fulfils a particularly
high identity-expressive function for individuals, and that is bought on impulse much
more frequently than goods with much lower identity-expressive potential, especially
basic body care products or tools. Thus, we expect that discount rates, and hence
consumer impulsivity, differ systematically with respect to type of consumer good. It has
not been examined previously whether identity-expressive goods are, in fact,
discounted more steeply than goods less likely to serve this psychological function.
Table 1. Identity-expressive function and impulse buying frequency of five types of consumer goods
Identity-expressive function
a
Impulse buying index
b
(among students)
Actual impulse buy frequency
(per month)
(Dittmar & Anderson, 2004) (Dittmar et al., 1996) (Dittmar, 2005b)
Clothes 5.0 2.13 1.57
Sports gear na
c
2.09 na
d
Music items 3.4 .122
e
0.39
e
Basic body care 2.7 2.34 0.34
Tools 2.0 na
f
na
d
a
Measured on six-point scales ranging from 1 not at all to 6 very much.
b
Less negative numbers indicate relatively higher impulse buying frequency.
c
This consumer good was included in the rating study.
d
This type of good was not coded separately in the diary study.
e
The apparent inconsistency between the index and actual impulse buy frequency is due to music items
being high-impulse goods among students, but not among older, general population samples.
f
This type of good was not included in the study.
756 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity deficits
Identity deficits or self-discrepancies (Higgins, 1987) are defined as the psychological
salience of perceived discrepancies between a person’s actual identity (how they are)
and their ideal identity (how they would ideally like to be). These should sensitize
individuals to the identity-expressive potential of material goods, as long as they view
material goods as suitable tools for improving one’s identity (Dittmar, in press). Identity
deficits are a psychologically uncomfortable state to be in (Gramzow, Sedikides, Panter,
& Insko, 2000), and individuals are therefore motivated to close or minimize their actual-
ideal self-discrepancies. Symbolic self-completion theory (Wicklund & Gollwitzer, 1982)
proposes that people make use of material goods, amongst other strategies, to
compensate for perceived identity deficits. Supportive evidence shows that business
students who lacked good qualifications, displayed more relevant material symbols,
such as an expensive watch, briefcase, or business suit, compared to students with
better career prospects (Wicklund & Gollwitzer, 1982). A later series of studies further
confirmed a compensatory relationship between increased use of material symbols and
lack of experience, expertise, or competence in occupational, domestic, or ideological
identity domains (Braun & Wicklund, 1989). Thus, identity deficits are seen in the
present research as a motivator of decisions aimed at reducing the gap between how a
consumer ‘is’ and ‘would ideally like to be’. However, in order for identity deficits to
impact consumer impulsivity, or discount rates, individuals need to believe that buying
material goods is a suitable compensatory strategy. In other words, it is a prerequisite
that consumers endorse a materialistic value orientation.
Endorsement of materialistic values
A person who endorses materialistic values believes that the acquisition of material
goods is a central life goal, a prime indicator of success, and a key to happiness and a
positive identity. The link between material goods and identity is a core feature of a
materialistic value orientation (e.g., Kasser & Kanner, 2004; Richins, 1995), and
materialistic individuals are particularly motivated to buy goods they think will bring
them closer to their ideal self (Dittmar, 2005a, 2007, in press). Thus, whether or not
individuals endorse materialistic values is important for consumer impulsivity because
materialism is assumed to channel an individual towards consumption as a compensatory
strategy to deal with perceived identity deficits. Indirect support for this proposal comes
from research that shows that individuals most likely to report excessive, uncontrolled
buying were both materialistic and high in identity deficits (Dittmar, 2004b). We propose
that endorsement of a materialistic value orientation is needed for identity deficits to
lead to impulse buying. For materialistic individuals, consumer impulsivity should be
greater, and hence discount rates steeper, the greater their identity deficits. For non-
materialists, identity deficits should not impact consumer impulsivity. Furthermore,
materialists’ impulsivity with respect to identity-expressive goods should be higher
when their identity deficits are made salient temporarily than when they are not.
The present research
In order to test our three predictors of consumer impulsivity, we use a temporal
discounting experimental paradigm. The desire to have a consumer good right now,
rather than to have to wait, is a preference concerning outcomes separated in time,
which can be captured by a discount rate. Individuals would want compensation for
Identity and consumers impulsivity 757
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
delaying a desired outcome, and the amount of compensation necessary for a given
delay, as a proportion of the initial value, is the discount rate. Thus, discount rates
measure the subjective ‘cost’ of delaying immediate gratification. In the matching
paradigm of intertemporal choice methodology (e.g., Benzion et al., 1989), respondents
match the utility of a good to be consumed now (e.g., £100) with a (larger) delayed good
of the same type in the future (e.g., £X 1 year from now), by setting X such that they
are indifferent between the two choices. An annual discount rate of 50% means that
a person demanded £150 as their ‘price’ to wait a year rather than receive £100
immediately. Temporal discounting offers an appropriate experimental paradigm within
which to study consumer impulsivity, since steep discounting would push the consumer
towards immediate gratification, and the link between discounting and impulsivity has
been made by Ainslie (2005) and in a recent review by Green and Myerson (2004).
Obviously, steep discounting does not invariably lead to impulse buying, as there are
further factors involved that could prove to be barriers, such as whether one is carrying
a credit card or not to make the purchase possible, but it is a cognitive decision
concerning the good which would push the consumer towards impulse buying.
Temporal discounting can be measured in ways other than the traditional compound
discount rate outlined above. One approach uses non-linear regression to fit a
hyperbolic discount function of subjective value (e.g., Green & Myerson, 2004; Rachlin,
2006). This method is not suitable for our data for two reasons. First, because we fix
current value (you can have £10 now) and ask respondents to set the point of
indifference for a specific delay (how much would you want in 10 days’ time), in effect
holding subjective value constant and getting people to vary the amount being
discounted. Second, the hyperbolic function fits badly at the individual level, especially
when there are limited data points (as in the present research), which led Myerson,
Green, and Warusawitharana (2001) to propose the area measure as an alternative.
Notwithstanding its many advantages, this is not as good a measure for the current
experiments as the discount rate, because we choose delays that are unequally
distributed over time, in order to capture the difference between very short time delays,
1 day or 5 days, and much longer delays, such as 6 months or 2 years. The differences
between the different delays affect the contribution of respondents’ judgments to the
overall measure, so that the area measure would predominantly reflect responses to long
delays, obscuring discounting at shorter delays. Yet, it is shorter delays that are of
greatest interest in the present research.
Three sets of discount rate predictions can be derived from our model of consumer
impulsivity. The first is that discount rates will differ systematically, depending on the
type of consumer good, such that rates are steeper for goods with high identity-
expressive potential (Studies 1–3). Second, discount rates for such goods will be related
systematically to a person’s stable identity deficits, but only if they endorse materialistic
values (Study 2). Third, and finally, making identity deficits temporarily salient for
materialistic individuals will increase their discount rates for a good that typically has
high identity-expressive potential (Study 3).
STUDY 1
The two aims of this first study were to (a) test a methodological innovation that
makes it possible to adapt the matching technique of the temporal discounting
paradigm to the study of different consumer goods and (b) to provide an initial
758 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
demonstration that discount rates differ systematically, depending on whether goods
are seen as having high or low identity-expressive potential (see Table 1), thus
addressing the first prediction of our model.
This study adapts the intertemporal choice matching paradigm by using vouchers for
different types of shop, which sell either goods with high identity-expressive potential
(such as fashionable clothes) or goods not likely to be identity expressive (such as basic
body care items like shampoo or nail clippers). In a repeated measures experimental
design, respondents are asked to imagine a particular kind of shop and the goods it sells
as vividly as possible, and then match the value of a voucher to be consumed now (e.g.,
£50) with a (larger) voucher that can be consumed only after a specified delay (e.g., £X
in 5 days time) by setting X such that they are indifferent between the immediate and
the delayed voucher. Money was included in addition to consumer goods. In order to
check whether this voucher adaptation is successful, we also assessed two well-
documented characteristics of discount rates, magnitude, and delay effects (Chapman,
1998; Green & Myerson, 2004), where individuals’ discount rates are higher for smaller
amounts of money, and for shorter delays.
Thus, the first hypothesis for Study 1 (1a) concerns two commonly observed
properties of discount rates, drawn from the earlier literature, whereas the second (1b)
addresses the first prediction of the proposed model of consumer impulsivity.
Replicating commonly found properties of discount rates is important in order to
validate our adaptation of the matching paradigm from money to different consumer
goods through vouchers.
Hypothesis 1a: Discount rates will show a magnitude effect (with smaller rates for larger
amounts of money), and a delay effect (with smaller rates for longer delays).
Hypothesis 1b: Discount rates will differ depending on the type of consumer good, such that
they are steeper for goods with high identity-expressive potential (clothes, sports gear) than for
goods low in that respect (basic body care products).
Method
Participants
The sample consisted of 100 undergraduate students at the University of Sussex (UK),
studying for a variety of degrees.
Stimuli, materials, and procedure
The task was presented on computer and participants were run individually. The
program started by explaining the matching task and presenting a trial item for a
consumer good not included in the study proper. After ‘Life often makes us choose
between something nice NOW, and something even nicer, but LATER’, the trial item ran
as follows:
Imagine that you win a prize in a shop that sells shoes that you really like. The prize is a
voucher to spend £75 on shoes in the shop, right now. Think about all the shoes you could
buy. Imagine yourself wearing them, and how they would feel on you.
Now imagine that you could swap this voucher for a (more valuable) voucher for the same
shop, but that you would not be allowed to spend it for 3 weeks.
Identity and consumers impulsivity 759
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
How much would the bigger voucher have to be worth so that you didn’t care whether you
got the £75 voucher now or the bigger voucher in 3 weeks?
(Respondent asked to enter an amount in full pounds Sterling).
In addition to making the matching task as transparent as possible, the wording was
intended to increase experimental realism and keep the respondent’s interest by inviting
them to imagine themselves as vividly as possible inside the shop and using the goods in
question. As soon as the respondent completed the trial item correctly (by entering an
amount exceeding £75), they started on the study proper, which asked them about
money and three types of consumer goods: clothes, sports gear, and body care products.
The delays were 5 days, 1 month, 6 months, and 2 years, and the amounts used were £10,
£50, and £200. In total, each respondent made 48 judgments. The items were presented
in blocks, containing all amount and delay combinations for one particular type of good,
and the wording introducing each new type of shop was the same as that given for the
trial item (e.g., sells clothes that you really like imagine yourself wearing
them ). The order of blocks, as well as amounts and delays within a block, were
randomized to counteract order and fatigue effects. After each item, respondents
entered the amount of money needed for them to wait in full pounds Sterling.
Results
Discount rates were calculated, according to a standard formula (e.g., Benzion ,et al.
1989), as
r
¼ ðv
d
=v
0
Þ
1=d
2 1:
where v
d
is the amount of money that the respondent entered as a ‘compensation price’
for having to wait, v
0
is the magnitude of the immediate (voucher) money value, and isd
the delay in days between the two. Responses that implied negative discount rates, in
that the delayed value was less than the immediate value, were dealt with in one of two
ways. Four respondents were omitted from the analysis for making more than five such
responses, on the grounds that they had either not understood the task or had
responded randomly. Other than this, such errors occurred very rarely (in less than 1%
of responses) and appeared to be errors in keying in the answer (e.g., £30 to wait 2 years
for an immediate £200 clothes vouchers, instead of £300); based on agreement between
two independent judges of the intended answer, their judgment was substituted for the
original response (in this case £300 instead of £30).
Overall, the discount rates we obtained typically were very high (particularly in
Study 2 reported later). However, the few studies that have used delays as short as ours
report comparable, or even higher, rates (e.g., Kirby, 1997). As in previous studies
(e.g., Loewenstein, 1988), the substantial positive skew of the response distribution was
normalized through natural logarithm transform. The log-transformed discount rates
were analysed by a 4 (three types of good and moneyÞ £ 3 ðmagnitude of
amountÞ £ 4 ðlength of delay) ANOVA with repeated measures on all factors, including
a trend analysis on amount and delay. We found significant magnitude and delay effects
consistent with Hypothesis 1a. Discount rates decline with increasing amount of money,
F
ð1; 95Þ ¼ 969:29; p , :001; h
2
p
¼ :91, and they also decline steeply with delay length,
F
ð1; 95Þ ¼ 1; 471:31; p , :001; h
2
p
¼ :94. The interaction between amount and delay
showed that the steepness of discounting curves over time is greater for smaller than
larger amounts of money,
Fð1; 95 75Þ ¼ :53; p , :001; h
2
p
¼ :44.
760 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
The role played by type of good was examined by three a priori orthogonal contrasts
with the first contrast central to testing Hypothesis 1b. Discount rates for the two types
of highly identity-expressive goods were compared with those for body care items. This
was followed by comparisons between the two identity-expressive goods, and between
money and the consumer goods taken together. Of central importance is the predicted
finding that discount rates differ significantly by type of consumer good,
2
such that rates
were significantly steeper for the identity-expressive goods (clothes and sports gear)
than for non-expressive goods (body care products), Fð1 95 14; Þ ¼ :14; 001;p , :
h
2
p
¼ :13. Geometric means of daily discount rates for these different consumer goods
are shown in Figure 1. In addition, the results for the second contrast show that clothes
were discounted even more steeply than sports gear,
Fð1; 95Þ ¼ 9:09; 01;p , : h
2
p
¼ :09,
whereas the third contrast comparing money with the average across the consumer
goods was not significant, Fð1 95; Þ ¼ :92; ns.
Discussion of Study 1
The magnitude and delay effects replicate hallmark characteristics of discount rates
commonly reported in the literature (Frederick et al., 2002; Green & Myerson, 2004). This
lends credence to the validity of our adaptation of the experimental matching paradigm,
which used vouchers for consumer goods as a methodological innovation. The central
finding that supports the first prediction of the proposed model of consumer impulsivity
is the systematic difference in discount rates between different types of consumer goods.
Respondents demanded significantly more compensation to wait for goods high in
identity-expressive potential, compared to a type of good that does not offer this
potential. Clothes were the consumer good that was most steeply discounted. Thus, the
proposal that discount rates are dependent on the type of consumer good was strongly
supported, which suggests stronger impulsivity with respect to goods that have high
identity-expressive potential, and these also make typical impulse buys.
The finding of the expected differential discount rates for high- and low-
identity-expressive goods is encouraging, but confidence would be strengthened by a
replication, preferably in a non-student sample. Furthermore, assuming that the
differential discount rates replicate, the second prediction of the proposed model of
consumer impulsivity needs to be addressed: that discount rates for identity-expressive
goods are related systematically to consumers’ identity deficits, as long as they endorse
a materialistic value orientation.
STUDY 2
This study had two aims. The first was to replicate the finding that discount rates differ
between consumer goods in a sample of adult consumers. Adult consumers are likely to
have higher incomes than students, more opportunities for impulse buying, and
possibly a greater diversity in terms of consumer impulsivity. The second aim was to test
whether discount rates can be predicted from individuals’ identity deficits, if they
endorse materialistic values. For materialistic individuals, but not non-materialists,
2
Two-way interactions between type of good and magnitude or delay, as well as three-way interactions were significant, but
with small effect sizes (largest
h
2
p
¼ :04, and more than half
h
2
p
# :03).
Identity and consumers impulsivity 761
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
we expect that their discount rates increase as a function of greater identity deficits, but
only for goods classified as having high identity-expressive potential, such as clothes.
The specific hypotheses examined were:
Hypothesis 2a: Discount rates for the identity-expressive good, clothes, will be steeper than for
the less identity-expressive goods, body care products, and music items (replication of Study 1).
Hypothesis 2b: For the identity-expressive good, clothes, but not the other goods, discount
rates will correlate positively with the extent of a person’s identity deficits, but only if they
endorse materialistic values.
Method
Participants
The sample consisted of 60 adult consumers, who had participated in a larger mail survey
(Dittmar, 2004b, 2005b). They volunteered to take part in this study as part of several
follow-up investigations, for which they received a payment of £10. In terms of consumer
behaviour, the sample was heterogeneous, including some individuals who had contacted
a self-help organization because they lacked self-control in their buying behaviour.
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
5 days 1 month 6 months 2 years
Delay
Daily % discount rate
Identity-expressive
Non-expressive
Figure 1. Discount rates of identity-expressive versus non-expressive goods at different delays (Study 1).
762 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Stimuli, materials, and procedure
This study was also computer-run and very similar to Study 1. In addition to money,
clothes and body care products were examined as high- and low-identity-expressive
goods, respectively, as in Study 1, but music items were included as a second good
comparatively low on identity expression potential among this older community
sample. The amounts of voucher money remained the same £10, £50, and £200 but
we decided to add an unusually short delay 2 1 day in order to be able to tap into
extreme consumer impulsivity that may manifest itself most strongly for a very short
time horizon. In order to keep the length of the experiment manageable, we deleted the
2-year delay used in Study 1, leaving four delays: 1 day, 5 days, 1 month, and 6 months.
Again, items were presented in blocks comprising all amount and delay combinations
for one particular type of good, randomized to counteract order and fatigue effects. Each
respondent made 48 judgments in total, completing the experiment in their own home
on a laptop computer brought by the researcher. They were asked afterwards to
comment on their experience of the discounting task.
Respondents’ identity deficits and materialistic values had been measured in the
larger mail survey in which these respondents had already participated (Dittmar,
2005a,b). We used our own measure of identity deficits, first described in Dittmar et al.
(1996), validated in Halliwell and Dittmar (2006), and discussed in detail in Dittmar
(2008, in press). It consists of a participant-generated self-discrepancy index (SDI),
which asks respondents to complete up to five sentences, of the format ‘I , but I
would like , using any word or set of words they liked, and then to rate each self-
discrepancy they generate in terms of its magnitude (size of discrepancy) and
psychological importance (concern or worry about the discrepancy), using five-point
Likert type scales ranging from not at all (1) to very much (5). As a global measure of
identity deficits, SDI is calculated by summing the products of the magnitude and
importance ratings of each self-discrepancy and then dividing by the number of
statements (Dittmar, in press). Thus,
SDI
¼
X
I
i
£ D
h i
=n;
where I
i
is the importance of attribute i, D
i
is the distance between actual and ideal self
on attribute i, and n is the number of sentences completed. SDI scores could range from
1 to 36.
Materialistic value endorsement was assessed by an established and validated scale
(Richins & Dawson, 1992) that showed excellent internal reliability (a ¼ :87). Example
items are ‘One of the most important achievements in life includes acquiring material
possessions’ and ‘I would like to own things that impress people’. Using a criterion
score close to the theoretical scale mid-point (established in the full survey sample of UK
consumers, 2004b
3
), respondents were classified as either endorsing materialistic
values (n ¼ 39) or not (n ¼ 18). This means that those classified as endorsing
materialism on average agreed with the scale items, whereas those who were classified
as non-materialists on average disagreed with the scale items. We are aware that using a
continuous measure of a variable is usually preferred to a dichotomous split, but we
3
This survey had 330 respondents, diverse in educational qualifications, occupation, and income, thus offering a more
empirically sound basis for classifying research participants as materialists or not than the smaller sample of respondents in the
present research, whose agreement to take part in follow-up studies is likely to indicate interest in consumption. The cut-off point
was both close to the empirical median split in the survey, 3.3, and to the theoretical mid-point of the materialism scale, 3.5.
Identity and consumers impulsivity 763
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
chose this strategy for two reasons. First, tests of interaction with continuous survey
measures, such as our materialism scale, often have less than 20% of the efficiency of
optimal experimental tests in detecting interaction effects (McClelland & Judd, 1993).
Second, our predictions are highly specific, such that we expect a positive correlation
between identity deficits and discount rates only in a particular subgroup of
respondents (those who can be said to have endorsed materialistic values) and for only
one type of consumer goods, clothes, which is unlikely to be reflected in an overall
interaction term.
Results
Log discount rates were calculated as in Study 1, and the very high discount rates for
short delays in the first study were also found here, particularly for the even shorter
delay of 1 day. The data of three individuals were omitted from the original sample of
60 according to the exclusion criteria employed in Study 1. The data were analysed by a
4 (three types of good and moneyÞ £ 3 (amount) by £ 4 (delay) repeated measures
ANOVA.
4
Highly significant findings for the magnitude and delay effects again replicate
the commonly reported characteristics of discount rates also found in Study 1: steeper
discounting with smaller amounts,
Fð1; 54 193Þ ¼ :76; p , :001; h
2
p
¼ :78, with shorter
delays,
Fð1 54 83; Þ ¼ :80; p , :001; h
2
p
¼ : :61, and their interaction, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 7 87;
p
, :01; h
2
p
¼ :13.
The role of different types of goods was again assessed by three a priori orthogonal
contrasts similar to those used in Study 1. The first compared discount rates for the
identity-expressive good, clothes, with the less expressive goods, body care, and music
items. The second compared the two less expressive goods, and the third compared
money with all three consumer goods combined. Consistent with Study 1 and
supporting the first hypothesis, discount rates differed significantly by type of consumer
good, such that rates were steeper for the identity-expressive good than for the other
goods,
Fð1 54 12; Þ ¼ :83; p , :001; h
2
p
¼ :19. Geometric means are shown in Figure 2.
The effect size was larger than in Study 1, and this may mean that adult consumers
discriminate more strongly between these different types of goods compared to
students. Music items and body care products did not differ significantly from each
other, Fð1 54; Þ ¼ 3:12; ns. In contrast to Study 1, money was discounted more steeply
than consumer goods,
Fð1 54 13; Þ ¼ :65; p , :001; h
2
p
¼ :20.
5
Thus, the central finding
is that discount rates were higher for the type of good that has high identity-expressive
potential than for types of goods that are less expressive of identity. This provides
support for Hypothesis 2a and replicates the student results in this more heterogeneous
adult sample.
We now turn to the second central question addressed in Study 2, which entails
a highly specific prediction of elevated discount rates. We expect that, for the
identity-expressive good, clothes, discount rates should be correlated positively with
the extent of a person’s identity deficits, but only if they endorse materialistic values.
4
Gender and whether individuals had been recruited via the buying behaviour self-help organization were also examined, but
did not yield systematic findings of interest for the present research.
5
In addition, two significant interaction effects were found for the contrast between goods high and low in identity-
expressive potential, showing that steeper discounting for short delays is amplified for identity-expressive goods,
Fð1 54; Þ ¼ 4:63; p , :05;
h
2
p
¼ :08, particularly in conjunction with vouchers for a smaller amount, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 6 36;:
p , :05;
h
2
p
¼ :11.
764 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
For non-materialists, identity deficits should not be related to discount rates for this, or
any, type of good. Figure 3 shows the correlations between identity deficits and discount
rates,
6
separately for materialists and non-materialists. For materialists, there was a
significant correlation, r ¼ :32, between their identity deficits and the discount rate
for clothes, whereas this correlation was close to zero for non-materialists, 03.r ¼ :
Constraining these correlations to be equal in a two-sample structural equation model
resulted in a significantly worse model fit,
Dx
2
ð1 4Þ ¼ :72, p , :01, indicating a
significant difference between them. As predicted, identity deficits were not signifi-
cantly correlated with discount rates for the less expressive goods, body care, and music
items, either for materialists or non-materialists. Thus, Hypothesis 2b was supported.
Discussion of Study 2
Overall, the results of Study 2 replicated those of Study 1 with respect to discount rates,
and hence consumer impulsivity: discount rates were higher for a type of good that is
highly expressive of identity, clothes, than for less expressive goods. Findings also
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
1 day 5 days 1 month 6 months
Delay
Daily % discount rate
Identity-expressive
Non-expressive
Figure 2. Adult consumers’ discount rates for identity-expressive versus non-expressive goods at
different delays (Study 2).
6
The patterns of associations were similar in the different delay and amount conditions.
Identity and consumers impulsivity 765
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
provide direct support for the proposal that discount rates for identity-expressive goods
can be predicted from a person’s materialistic value endorsement and identity deficits.
For materialistic individuals, higher identity deficits are systematically related to
demanding higher compensation for waiting to consume an identity-expressive good,
clothes, but not less expressive goods. As predicted, individuals who do not endorse
materialist values showed no links between discounting and identity deficits.
Possible criticisms of the discounting methodology we employed could be that the
task may be artificial, or that discount rates are not directly related to actual consumer
decision making in retail environments. However, the follow-up, where respondents
commented on their experience of the discounting task, showed that less than 4% found
the task boring or meaningless, and several respondents reported excitement, and even
physiological reactions, such as raised heart beat, confirming that our sample had
engaged with the task and took it seriously. More importantly, with respect to actual
decision making in shops, it was possible to calculate correlations between individuals’
discount rates for clothes and the frequency with which they had actually purchased
clothes impulsively in the previous month, as recorded in the separate shopping diary
study. Despite the short time span of the diaries (1 month), there are significant
correlations between respondents’ total number of impulse purchases of clothes and
Materialists
Non-materialists
Identity deficits
Clothes
Music items
Body care products
.32**
–.01
ns
–.02
ns
Identity deficits
Clothes
Music items
Body care products
.03
ns
.03
ns
–.19
ns
**
p
<.01
Figure 3. Correlations between materialists’ and non-materialists’ identity deficits and discount rates
for different types of consumer goods.
766 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
discount rates at both 1 month’s delay, r ¼ :30; 05, and 6 months’ delay, 33;p , : r ¼ :
p , :05. Thus, there is good evidence that those who have higher discount rates in this
study are actually more likely to have made impulsive purchases of that type of good
during the previous month.
Finally, this study examined identity deficits as a stable individual difference variable
and found, as predicted, systematic links for materialistic individuals between the extent
of their identity deficits and consumer impulsivity for a type of good that is typically seen
as offering high identity-expressive potential. Yet, perceived identity deficits can
fluctuate to some extent depending on context (e.g., Boldero & Francis, 2000; Dittmar,
Halliwell, & Stirling, 2009); people feel better about themselves at certain times and
worse at others. This suggests that implications of the proposed model could be tested
further through an experimental manipulation of temporary identity deficit salience.
STUDY 3
Two main aims guided this final study. The first was to replicate again that there are
differential discount rates for different types of consumer goods. In this instance, we
decided to compare clothes, as a typical identity-expressive good, with a new low-
expressive good that may be more similar to clothes than basic body care products in
terms of unit price and likely time course of consumption. It was decided to use tools for
home and garden (e.g., tool kit, cordless drill) because tools are more costly than many
body care items and are consumed over a longer period of time, making them more
comparable to clothes on these dimensions. As already reported (see Table 1), tools are
not used for identity expression, in contrast to clothes. The second aim of this study was
to test whether a manipulation of the salience of materialistic individuals’ identity
deficits would impact on the discounting of identity-expressive goods. In the previous
study, perceived identity deficits were examined as a stable individual difference, but
they can also be examined as a temporary construct (Dittmar & Halliwell, 2005; Dittmar,
Halliwell, & Stirling, 2009). Such a conceptualization is consistent with evidence related
to self-discrepancy theory that shows that temporarily accessible constructs can have a
stronger influence on information processing than chronically accessible constructs
(Bargh, Lombardi, & Higgins, 1988). Asking respondents to list identity deficits can be
justified as a valid manipulation of their temporary salience, given that we have
demonstrated that completing the SDI leads respondents to focus on subjectively
meaningful gaps between their actual and ideal self (Halliwell & Dittmar, 2006).
Temporarily aroused identity deficits are a good predictor of momentary negative affect,
with negative affect a well-documented consequence of self-discrepancies (Dittmar,
Halliwell, & Stirling, 2009). Thus, we expect that heightened salience of identity deficits
would lead individuals to experience greater impulsivity, reflected by higher discount
rates for goods useful for expressing and improving one’s identity, provided they endorse
materialistic values and therefore use consumption as a deficit-reduction strategy.
Respondents for the present study were volunteers from the consumer panel of a
large, multinational manufacturer of consumer goods. The sample was women, with
clothes and tools as the two consumer goods examined, which differ strongly in their
identity-expressive potential (see Table 1). The salience manipulation of identity deficits
was simple and mild. Half the respondents were asked to complete the SDI directly
before the discounting task, and the other half afterwards. Thus, for half of the
respondents identity deficits were made salient when they considered compensation for
Identity and consumers impulsivity 767
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
having to wait to obtain clothes and tools, but not for the other half. There were two
hypotheses:
Hypothesis 3a: Discount rates will be higher for the identity-expressive good (clothes) than for
non-expressive good (tools), replicating Studies 1 and 2.
Hypothesis 3b: Making identity deficits salient will have a systematic impact on discount rates for
the identity-expressive good (clothes) compared to the non-expressive good (tools), but only
for materialistic individuals. Specifically, materialistic individuals are expected to report a greater
difference in discount rates between the clothes and tools when identity deficits are salient than
when they are not salient.
Method
Participants
The sample consisted of 72 women who volunteered to take part in this study while
serving on the consumer panel of a multinational manufacturing company, half in the
high (n ¼ 34) and half (n ¼ 33) in the low identity deficits salience condition.
Stimuli, materials, and procedure
In order to enable data collection in the company, the discounting methodology had to
be adapted from being computer-run to questionnaire-based. Vouchers were valued at
£50 and £200 at each of four delays, 1 day, 5 days, 1 months, and 6 months, resulting in
eight items per type of good. Respondents considered one item at a time, which was
ensured through individual administration and concealment of later items. As in Studies
1 and 2, items were presented in a block for clothes and for tools and, within each block,
respondents completed the items in a fixed order (which had been randomly
determined). They then completed the same materialism scale as used in Study 2
(Richins & Dawson, 1992; a ¼ :72).
Half the respondents completed the SDI before the discounting task and half
afterwards.
7
Thus, in the salient condition, they reported identity deficits directly
before discounting consumer goods, whereas they reported identity deficits afterwards
in the non-salient condition. Self-discrepancies were assessed as in Study 2, by the SDI,
that asked respondents to complete five open-ended sentences concerning aspects that
they would like to change about themselves, and then rate each self-discrepancy in
terms of its magnitude and importance.
Results
Five participants were omitted from the original sample of 72 (see Study 1 for a
description of exclusion criteria). With respect to replicating the findings of Studies 1
and 2, discount rates were first analysed by a 2 (type of good ) £ 2 (magnitude) £ 4 (delay)
ANOVA with repeated measures on all factors. Magnitude and delay effects replicated
7
In order to make the two conditions more comparable, we included a further task that also involved participants in thinking
about the self, but would prevent them from considering shortcomings in their self-concept. Respondent simply wrote down
‘five things that you like about yourself ’.
768 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
again, such that steeper discounting was found for the lower voucher amount,
F
ð1; 66Þ ¼ 95:91; p , :001; h
2
p
¼ : : :59, and at shorter delays Fð1; 66Þ ¼ 32 53; p , 001;
h
2
p
¼ :33. Of central importance is the significant main effect for type of consumer good,
with discount rates steeper for clothes than for tools, as predicted, Fð1 66 13 10;; Þ ¼ :
p
¼ :001; h
2
p
¼ :17. The mean daily discount rate for clothes was 1.09%, compared to
0.84% for tools. Thus, the finding that a type of good that affords identity expression is
discounted more steeply than a non-expressive good replicated once again. The close
match between clothes and tools in unit cost and time course of consumption adds
confidence to the robustness of this effect.
In order to examine the effect of experimentally manipulating the salience of identity
deficits on discount rates, a single SDI score was calculated as in Study 2. There was no
systematic difference in SDI score between respondents in the two salience conditions,
tð65Þ ¼ 21:17; ns, thus excluding the possibility that pre-existing differences in identity
deficits between individuals allocated to the salient versus non-salient condition could
account for differences in discount rates.
In order to test Hypothesis 3b, which predicted an interaction effect between type of
good and temporary salience of identity deficits only for materialists, analyses were
run separately for individuals with (n ¼ 47) and without ( 20) endorsementn ¼
of materialistic values (using the same classification as in Study 2). Given our interest
in systematic differences, we analysed log-transformed discount rates (averaged
across magnitude and delay salience of identity deficits)Þ £ 2 ðtype of goodÞ £ 2 ð
ANOVAs, with SDI as a covariate. In this way, we controlled for the extent of
individuals’ identity deficits, isolating the impact of the experimental salience
manipulation. The central concern of this study is to demonstrate that the impact of
identity deficits made temporarily salient on discount rates results in a significant
interaction between type of good and identity deficit salience, but only for materialistic
individuals.
8
As expected, this interaction was not significant for non-materialistic
individuals endorsement,
Fð1; 18Þ ¼ 0:11; ns; h
2
p
¼ :01. In contrast, the predicted
interaction between goods and salience condition was significant for materialistic
individuals,
Fð1; 43 4Þ ¼ :77; 05;p , : h
2
p
¼ :10, and mean daily discount rates are shown
in Figure 4.
The means show that discount rates for the identity-expressive good, clothes,
increase to some extent when materialistic consumers’ identity deficits are made salient,
compared to when they are not salient. Although we did not necessarily expect that
making identity deficits salient would impact on discount rates for the non-expressive
good, tools, it appears they are lower after identity deficits are made salient. In other
words, identity deficits salience appears to lead materialistic consumers to differentiate
more strongly between goods high and low in identity-expressive potential. Indeed, a
test for simple effects shows that, whereas the difference in discounting between
clothes and tools did not reach significance in the non-salient condition,
Fð1; 44Þ ¼ 1:27; ns, it was highly significant when identity deficits are salient,
Fð1; 44Þ ¼ 44:24; p , :001. Thus, making identity deficits temporarily salient seems
to make materialistic consumers more inclined towards impulsivity for identity-
expressive goods, such as clothes, that are relevant to their ideal self, in contrast to less
expressive goods.
8
Main effects for salience condition were not significant, neither for materialists, Fð1 43 0; Þ ¼ :07; ns;
h
2
p
¼ :00, nor
non-materialists, Fð1 18 0; Þ ¼ :90; ns;
h
2
p
¼ :05.
Identity and consumers impulsivity 769
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Discussion of Study 3
The differential discounting of goods high and low in identity-expressive potential
appears a robust finding, given that it was replicated again in this third study using a
different sample of adult consumers. The predicted interaction between type of good
and identity deficits salience for materialistic individuals provides further support for
the model of consumer impulsivity proposed. When materialistic individuals focus on
their identity deficits, they demonstrate significantly greater impulsivity for a good likely
to help them express or improve their identity than for a non-expressive good.
Moreover, this effect was demonstrated after a rather mild manipulation of identity
deficits: respondents had merely listed aspects of themselves that they would like to
change directly before the discounting task. Clearly, there are much stronger cues for
materialistic individuals’ identity deficits to become temporarily salient, such as
comments from family or peers, stimuli present in the shopping environment, or
possibly through social comparison with ideal models in the media (Dittmar, 2008;
Richins, 1995).
CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS
The three experimental studies reported provide good evidence for the first prediction
derived from the proposed model of consumer impulsivity. They demonstrate the novel
finding that discount rates differ systematically between types of consumer goods:
people are less willing to delay immediate consumption of goods that offer high identity-
expressive potential. The present studies, by necessity, examined a limited range of
types of consumer goods. Clothes are a typical good used for the expression and
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.4
IDs not salient IDs salient
Daily discount rates %
Tools Clothes
Figure 4. Materialistic individuals’ discount rates for identity-expressive versus non-expressive goods
by identity deficits salience.
770 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
improvement of identity across different age and social groups, whereas sports gear is
likely to be more identity-expressive on average among younger respondents, such as
students. Basic body care products, such as shampoo or nail clippers, do not offer much
by the way of identity expression or repair for any social group, whereas the non-
expressiveness of tools could be gender-related, being more characteristic of women
than men. Finally, the low identity expressiveness of music items is likely to be age-
related, given that music items appear to play a much stronger role for identity among
young, and particularly adolescent, people (e.g., Dittmar, Barker, & Bond, 2009;
Rentfrow & Gosling, 2003) than in our sample of middle-aged consumers. Clearly, goods
can vary in identity-expressive potential among different groups of people, although
clothes and body care items seem to be generally regarded as high and low in identity-
expressive potential. Ideally, a range of different consumer goods would be examined in
a single experiment, but given the maximum number of discounting decisions each
respondent could sensibly be expected to make without undue fatigue meant that not
more than three goods could be examined in any one study. Thus, future research may
wish to identify additional goods particularly high and low in identity-expressive
potential not examined in the present research. Moreover, it is possible that the goods
we studied vary on dimensions other than identity-expressive potential, such as unit
cost or time course of consumption, and further research may wish to address explicitly
whether such dimensions have an additional impact on discounting, or interact in some
way with identity-expressive potential. Yet, notwithstanding the need to examine a
greater diversity of types of goods, as well as additional characteristics of goods, steeper
discounting for identity-expressive goods compared to non-expressive goods was
replicated in three studies, with different samples, and using somewhat different
combinations of goods. This convergence lends strength to the potential generalizability
of this finding.
In addition to predicting that type of consumer goods is an identity-related factor
that impacts impulsivity, our new model of consumer impulsivity predicts that
materialistic individuals’ identity deficits should be systematically linked to greater
impulsivity, but only for goods that afford identity expression. This prediction was
supported in Study 2 with respect to individuals’ stable identity deficits and in Study 3
with respect to the temporary salience of identity deficits. These findings, taken
together, support the interpretation that identity-seeking constitutes a novel, hitherto
neglected, but significant dimension of temporal discounting, and therefore consumer
impulsivity. Thus, the individual difference factors in the proposed model that
increase impulsivity constitute psychological motives that can be interpreted as identity-
seeking. Endorsement of materialistic values can be seen as a commitment to identity
construction through the symbolic potential of material goods, and identity deficits
consist of gaps between individuals’ actual and ideal selves that they are motivated
to close. Thus, materialistic individuals are motivated to move closer to their ideal
self through making use of material goods with high identity-symbolic potential.
In terms of theoretical implications, the proposed model is innovative in providing
an account of, and empirical support for, specific individual difference factors that
increase consumer impulsivity, all of which are related to identity.
From the perspective of economic theory, the point could be made that materialistic
consumers derive utility from discounting clothes particularly steeply if, indeed, they
can close, or minimize their identity deficits successfully when they by this type of
consumer good on impulse (e.g., Borghans et al., 2008). However, there are theoretical
reasons why this is unlikely to be the case: the pursuit of identity-expressive goods can
Identity and consumers impulsivity 771
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
raise confidence or competence momentarily, but is not suited to solving the more
essential and common reasons for identity deficits, such as a lack of close interpersonal
relationships, community belonging, or a sense of meaning in one’s life (Dittmar,
Banerjee, & Bond, 2009; Vignoles, in press). Moreover, we have shown empirically in
shopping diary studies that, although the perceived boost in identity-related benefits is
greater in more materialistic individuals directly after the impulse purchase, it has
dissipated by the time people get home with their purchase in contrast to less
materialistic consumers (Dittmar, 2001, 2008).
With respect to applied implications, the finding in Study 3 that identity-expressive
goods are discounted more steeply when identity deficits are made salient to
materialistic individuals raises the question of how malleable the perception of one’s
identity deficits can be, and whether impulse buying might increase when individuals
are made to feel bad about certain aspects of themselves. On the one hand, this raises
worrying implications from a consumer point of view, where marketers could decide to
deliberately devise in-store stimuli aimed at increasing consumer identity deficits.
Indeed, some would argue that this is already the case (Kilbourne, 2006). On the other
hand, it also offers an evidence-based foundation for consumer education, where
individuals, especially less experienced consumers (such as adolescents), could be
alerted to this link between identity deficits and impulse buying. The idea that consumer
education, as part of the school curriculum, can help guard against uncontrolled buying
has already been piloted in a European Union project (Garce´s Prieto, 2002).
Two areas of future research on materialistic value endorsement and identity deficits
as predictors of consumer impulsivity deserve particular mention. The first would be an
extension to impulsive purchasing in actual retail environments. For example,
individuals’ endorsement of materialistic values could be assessed and their identity
deficits made salient before they enter a shop or store, and then their purchases of
identity-expressive goods could be used to assess the impact of this field experimental
manipulation.
9
Second, a dimension of consumer impulsivity particularly worthy of
future research attention is the disregard for financial constraints and consequences.
The model proposed here could be extended from discount rates to studying the extent
and frequency of individuals’ impulse buying over time as an outcome of type of good,
materialistic value endorsement and identity deficits, which in turn may be an important
predictor of individual personal debt given alarming debt levels in the UK (Creditaction,
2006) and other developed countries, particularly in the current global climate of credit
crunch (Creditaction, 2009). Given the increasing drive towards consumerism (Dittmar,
2004a, 2007, 2008; Kasser & Kanner, 2004), such an examination would be both timely
and topical.
Acknowledgements
The research reported in this paper was supported by Economic and Social Research Council
grant L122251012 as part of the Economic Beliefs and Behaviour Programme. Special thanks go to
Jonathan Baron, Graham Loomes, and Paul Sparks for their helpful comments on earlier versions
of this paper, to Peter Taylor-Gooby for his support and help as Programme Director, to Susanne
Friese who worked as research assistant on the project, and to Nick Anderson for his help with the
9
Such experimental work would, of course, need to be handled with great ethical care, but could also offer opportunities for
consumer advice and education.
772 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
data collection for Study 3. We would particularly like to acknowledge the invaluable contribution
of Jane Beattie (co-grant holder with H. D.), who conceptualized the first two studies reported and
worked on them until her tragic death shortly before the project ended.
References
Abratt, R., & Goodey, S. D. (1990). Unplanned buying and in-store stimuli in supermarkets.
Managerial and Decision Economics, 11, 111–121.
Ainslie, G. (1975). Specious reward: A behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control.
Psychological Bulletin, 82, 463–496.
Ainslie, G. (1992). Picoeconomics: The strategic interaction of successive motivational states
within the person. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ainslie, G. (2005). Precis of breakdown of will. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28, 635–673.
Bargh, J. A., Lombardi, W. J., & Higgins, E. T. (1988). Automaticity of chronically accessible
constructs in person
*
situation effects on person perception: It’s just a matter of time. Journal
of Personality and Social Psychology, 55(4), 599–605.
Baron, J., Badgio, P., & Gaskins, I. W. (1986). Cognitive style and its improvement: A normative
approach. In R. J. Sternberg (Ed.), Advances in the psychology of human intelligence (Vol. 3,
pp. 173–220). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Baumeister, R. F. (2002). Yielding to temptation: Self-control failure, impulsive purchasing, and
consumer behavior. Journal of Consumer Research, 28, 670–676.
Baumeister, R. F., & Vohs, K. D. (2003). Sustaining delay of gratification over time: A hot–cool
systems perspective. In G. Loewenstein, D. Read, & R. Baumeister (Eds.), Time and decision:
Economic and psychological perspectives on intertemporal choice (pp. 201–216). New York:
Russell Sage Foundation.
Baumeister, R. F., Vohs, K. D., & Tice, D. M. (2008). Self-regulation: Goals, consumption, and
choices. In C. P. Haugtvedt, P. M. Herr, & F. R. Kardes (Eds.), Handbook of consumer
psychology: Marketing and consumer psychology series (pp. 349–366). New York: Taylor &
Francis/Erlbaum.
Bellenger, D. N., Robertson, D. H., & Hirschman, E. C. (1978). Impulse buying varies by product.
Journal of Advertising Research, 18, 15–18.
Benzion, U., Rapoport, A., & Yagil, J. (1989). Discount rates inferred from decisions: An
experimental study. Management Science, 35, 270–284.
Boldero, J., & Francis, J. (2000). The relation between self-discrepancies and emotion: The
moderating roles of self-guide importance, location relevance, and social self-domain
centrality. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 78, 38–52.
Borghans, L., Duckworth, A. L., Heckman, J., & ter Weel, B. (2008). The economics and
psychology of personality traits. Journal of Human Resources, 43, 972–1059.
Borghans, L., & Goldsteyn, B. H. H. (2006). Time discounting and the body mass index, evidence
from The Netherlands. Economics and Human Biology, 4, 39–61.
Braun, O. L., & Wicklund, R. A. (1989). Psychological antecedents of conspicuous consumption.
Journal of Economic Psychology, 10, 161–187.
Chapman, G. (1998). Sooner or later: The psychology of intertemporal choice. Psychology of
Learning and Motivation, 38, 83–113.
Creditaction (2006). Debt facts and figures compiled 4th May 2006. Retrieved from
www.creditaction.org.uk/debtstats.htm
Creditaction (2009). Total UK personal debt. Retrieved from www.credit action.org.uk/debt-
statistics.html
Csikszentmihalyi, M., & Rochberg-Halton, E. (1981). The meaning of things: Domestic symbols
and the self. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cushman, P. (1990). Why the self is empty: Toward a historically situated psychology. American
Psychologist 45, , 599–611.
Identity and consumers impulsivity 773
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Dittmar, H. (1989). Gender identity-related meanings of personal possessions. British Journal of
Social Psychology, 28, 159–171.
Dittmar, H. (1992). The social psychology of material possessions: To have is to be. Harvester
Wheatsheaf/St Martin’s Press: Hemel Hempstead/New York.
Dittmar, H. (2000). The role of self-image in excessive buying. In A. Benson (Ed.), I shop, therefore
I am: Compulsive buying and the search for self (pp. 105–132). New York: Aronson.
Dittmar, H. (2001). Impulse buying in ordinary and ‘compulsive’ consumers. In J. Baron,
G. Loomes, & E. Weber (Eds.), Conflict and tradeoffs in decision-making. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Dittmar, H. (2004a). Are you what you have? Consumer society and our sense of identity.
Psychologist 17, , 206–210.
Dittmar, H. (2004b). Understanding and diagnosing compulsive buying. In R. Coombs (Ed.),
Handbook of addictive disorders: A practical guide to diagnosis and treatment (chap. 13,
pp. 411–450). New York: Wiley.
Dittmar, H. (2005a). A new look at ‘compulsive buying’: Self-discrepancies and materialistic values
as predictors of compulsive buying tendency. Journal of Social and Clinical Psychology, 24,
806–833.
Dittmar, H. (2005b). Compulsive buying behaviour a growing concern? An empirical exploration
of the role of gender, age, and materialism. British Journal of Psychology, 96, 467–491.
doi:10.1348/000712605X53533
Dittmar, H. (2007). The costs of consumer culture and the ‘cage within’: The impact of the
material ‘good life’ and ‘body perfect’ ideals on individuals’ identity and well-being.
Commentary on Kasser, T., Cohn, S., Kanner, A. D., & Ryan, R. M. (2007). Some costs of
American corporate capitalism: A psychological exploration of value and goal conflicts.
Psychological Inquiry, 18, 1–9.
Dittmar, H. (2008). Consumer society, identity, and well-being: The search for the ‘good life’ and
the ‘body perfect’. In R. Brown (Ed.), European Monographs in Social Psychology Series. East
Sussex/New York: Psychology Press.
Dittmar, H. (in press). Material and consumer identities. In S. J. Schwartz, K. Luyckx, &
V. L. Vignoles (Eds.), Handbook of identity theory and research (chap. 31). New York:
Springer. To appear.
Dittmar, H., & Anderson, N. (2004). Identity-expressive function of four types of consumer goods.
Unpublished manuscript, University of Sussex.
Dittmar, H., Banerjee, R., & Bond, R. (2009). Materialism and well-being: The role of perceived
peer pressure and identity deficits. Manuscript submitted for publication.
Dittmar, H., Barker, L., & Bond, R. (2009). Who is taking the rap? Correlational and experimental
associations between adolescent boys’ identification with rap music and their body
dissatisfaction. Manuscript in preparation.
Dittmar, H., & Beattie, J. (1998). Impulsive and excessive buying behaviour. In P. Taylor-Gooby
(Ed.), Choice and public policy (pp. 123–144). London: Macmillan.
Dittmar, H., Beattie, J., & Friese, S. (1995). Gender identity and material symbols: Objects and
decision considerations in impulse purchases. Journal of Economic Psychology, 16, 491–511.
(Also available on the world-wide web: http://www.ukc.ac.uk/ESRC/).
Dittmar, H., Beattie, J., & Friese, S. (1996). Objects, decision considerations and self-image in men’s
and women’s impulse purchases [Special Issue on Decision-making and Emotions]. Acta
Psychologica 93, , 187–206. (Also available on the world-wide web: http://www.ukc.ac.uk/
ESRC/).
Dittmar, H., & Drury, J. (2000). Self-image is it in the bag? A qualitative comparison between
‘ordinary’ and ‘excessive’ consumers. Journal of Economic Psychology, 21, 109–142.
Dittmar, H., & Halliwell, E. (2005). The role of self-beliefs in women’s responses to idealised media
images. Funded by the UK’s Economic and Social Research Council’s (ESRC) grant RES-000-22-
0774. A research report detailing the main findings can be downloaded at www.esrcsociety
today.ac.uk/ESRCInfoCentre
774 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Dittmar, H., Halliwell, E., & Stirling, E. (2009). Understanding the impact of thin media models on
women’s body-focused affect: The roles of thin-ideal internalization and weight-related self-
discrepancy activation in experimental exposure effects. Journal of Social and Clinical
Psychology, 28(1), 43–72.
Estle, S. J., Green, L., Myerson, J., & Holt, D. D. (2007). Discounting of monetary and directly
consumable rewards. , 58–63.Psychological Science, 18
Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference:
A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351–401.
Garce´s Prieto, J. (2002). Experiencias de trabajo en la prevencio`n y tratamiento de’ la adiccio`n al
consumo. In. I. Garcı´a Ureta & E. Olibarri Ferna´ndez (Eds.), El consumo y la adiccio
`
n a las
compras: Diferentes perspectivas (pp. 199–222). Bilbao: University of the Basque Country.
An English summary can be found in Nice-Mail, May 2000, News and Information about
Consumer Education, 13, 16-17 Last accessed 22nd December 2009 at http://www/info-
consumo.es/escuela/web/nice/eng/nice_13.pdf
Gramzow, R. H., Sedikides, C., Panter, A. T., & Insko, C. A. (2000). Aspects of self-regulation and
self-structure as predictors of perceived emotional distress. Personality and Social Psychology
Bulletin 26, , 188–205.
Green, L., Fry, A. F., & Myerson, J. (1994). Discounting of delayed rewards: A life-span comparison.
Psychological Science, 5, 33–36.
Green, L., & Myerson, J. (2004). A discounting framework for choice with delayed and
probabilistic rewards. , 769–792.Psychological Bulletin, 130
Halliwell, E., & Dittmar, H. (2006). The role of appearance-related self-discrepancies for young
adults’ affect, body image, and emotional eating: A comparison of fixed-item and respondent-
generated self-discrepancy measures. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 32,
447–458.
Hausmann, A. (2000). A multi-method investigation of consumer motivations in impulse buying
behaviour. Journal of Consumer Marketing, 17, 403–419.
Herabadi, A., Verplanken, B., & van Knippenberg, A. (2009). Consumption experience of impulse
buying in Indonesia: Emotional arousal and hedonistic considerations. Asian Journal of Social
Psychology, 12, 20–31.
Higgins, T. (1987). Self-discrepancy: A theory relating self to affect. Psychological Review, 94,
319–340.
Hoch, S. J., & Loewenstein, G. F. (1991). Time-inconsistent preferences and consumer self-control.
Journal of Consumer Research, 17, 1–16.
Kamptner, N. (1991). Personal possessions and their meanings: A life-span perspective.
In F. W. Rudmin (Ed.), To have possessions: A handbook on ownership and property
[Special issue]. Journal of Social Behavior and Personality, 6, 209–228.
Kasser, T., & Kanner, A. D. (Eds.), (2004). Psychology and consumer culture: The struggle for a
good life in a materialistic world. Washington, DC: American Psychological Association.
Kilbourne, J. (2006, September). Jesus is a brand of jeans. New Internationalist, 10–12.
Kirby, K. N. (1997). Bidding on the future: Evidence against normative discounting of delayed
rewards. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 126, 54–70.
Loewenstein, G. (2000). Emotions in economic theory and economic behavior. American
Economic Review, Paper Proceedings, 90, 426–432.
Loewenstein, G., Read, D., & Baumeister, R. (2003). Time and decision: Economic and
psychological perspectives on intertemporal choice. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Loewenstein, G. F. (1988). Frames of mind in intertemporal choice. ,Management Science, 34
200–214.
Loewenstein, G. F. (1996). Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational
Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 272–292.
Martin, L. E., & Potts, G. F. (2009). Impulsivity in decision-making: An event-related investigation.
Personality and Individual Differences, 46, 303–308.
Identity and consumers impulsivity 775
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
McClelland, G. H., & Judd, C. M. (1993). Statistical difficulties of detecting interactions and
moderator effects. Psychological Bulletin, 114, 376–390.
Mischel, W., Ayduk, O., & Mendoza-Denton, R. (2003). Sustaining delay of gratification over time:
A hot–cool systems perspective. In G. Loewenstein, D. Read, & R. Baumeister (Eds.), Time and
decision: Economic and psychological perspectives on intertemporal choice (pp. 175–200).
New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Myerson, J., Green, L., & Warusawitharana, M. (2001). Area under the curve as a measure of
discounting. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 76, 235–243.
Odum, A. L., Baumann, A. A. L., & Rimington, D. D. (2006). Discounting of delayed hypothetical
money and food: Effects of amount. Behavioural Processes, 73, 278–284.
Odum, A. L., & Rainaud, C. P. (2003). Discounting of delayed hypothetical money, alcohol, and
food. Behavioural Processes, 64, 305–313.
Ostaszewski, P. (1996). The relation between temperament and rate of temporal discounting.
European Journal of Personality, 10, 161–172.
Rachlin, H. (2006). Notes on discounting. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior,
85, 425–435.
Read, D., & Read, N. L. (2004). Time discounting over the lifespan. Organizational Behavior and
Human Decision Processes, 94, 22–32.
Rentfrow, P. J., & Gosling, S. D. (2003). The do re mi’s of everyday life: The structure and
personality correlates of music preferences. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,
84, 1236–1256.
Richins, M. L. (1995). Social comparison, advertising, and consumer discontent. American
Behavioral Scientist, 38, 593–607.
Richins, M. L., & Dawson, S. (1992). Materialism as a consumer value: Measure development and
validation. Journal of Consumer Research, 19, 303–316.
Rook, D. W. (1987). The buying impulse. Journal of Consumer Research, 14, 189–199.
Sedikides, C., & Brewer, M. (Eds.), (2001). Individual self, relational self, collective self.
New York: Psychology Press.
Solomon, M. R. (1985). The psychology of fashion. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Strotz, R. H. (1956). Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. Review of
Economic Studies, 23, 165–180.
Vignoles, V. L. (in press). Identity motives. To appear. In S. J. Schwartz, K. Luyckx, & V. L. Vignoles
(Eds.), Handbook of identity theory and research (chap. 31). New York: Springer.
Vignoles, V. L., Regalia, C., Manzi, C., Golledge, J., & Scabini, E. (2006). Beyond self-esteem:
The influence of multiple motives on identity construction. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 90, 308–333.
Verplanken, B., & Herabadi, A. (2001). Individual differences in impulse buying tendency:
Feeling and no thinking. European Journal of Personality, 15, 72–83.
Wicklund, R. A., & Gollwitzer, P. M. (1982). Symbolic self-completion. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Winston, G. C. (1980). Addiction and backsliding: A theory of compulsive consumption.
Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 1, 295–324.
Received 17 May 2006; revised version received 30 November 2009
776 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
| 1/26

Preview text:

Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 751 The British Psychological
British Journal of Psychology (2010), 101, 751–776 Society
q 2010 The British Psychological Society www.bpsjournals.co.uk
‘I want it and I want it now’: Using a temporal
discounting paradigm to examine predictors of consumer impulsivity Helga Dittmar* and Rod Bond
University of Sussex, Brighton, UK
This paper proposes a new model of consumer impulsivity, using type of good, a
person’s endorsement of materialistic values, and identity deficits as predictors.
Traditional decision making and psychological accounts see impulsive behaviour as a
general overweighing of short-term gratification (I want that dress now) relative to
longer-term concerns, irrespective of consumer good. Our proposal is that consumers’
impulsivity (a) differs according to type of good and (b) is linked systematically to a
combination of materialistic values and high identity deficits. Beginning with Study 1,
three experiments, using a temporal discounting paradigm, show consistently that
discount rates are higher for goods that are seen as highly expressive of identity (e.g.,
clothes) than goods not expressive of identity (e.g., basic body care products). For
materialistic consumers, identity deficits predict discount rates for identity-expressive
goods (Study 2), and discount rates change for materialistic individuals when their
identity deficits are made salient (Study 3). These findings support a conceptualization
of consumer impulsivity as identity-seeking behaviour.
Impulsivity can be described as ‘acting without thinking’, where people are more
motivated by immediate reward, rather than by long-term consequences of their
behaviour. This characteristic of everyday decision making also applies to wanting
particular consumer goods now, rather than planning consumption over time to
maximize long-term satisfaction. Consumers often experience conflict between desiring
particular goods right now, on the spur of the moment, and wanting to spend their
money sensibly on objects from which they can be sure to derive benefits over time.
When the short-term desire wins out, the consumer engages in impulse buying. In a
qualitative study, consumers defined impulse buying as ‘Just buying it, quickly, without
going away and thinking about it, buying it straight away’ or ‘Something I see and don’t
plan and I think “I’d like that”’ (Dittmar & Drury, 2000, pp. 123–124). In this paper,
we define consumer impulsivity as decisions about material goods that are characterized
by a strong, immediate desire for the good in question, lack of deliberation or planning,
* Correspondence should be addressed to Dr Helga Dittmar, School of Psychology, Pevensey 1, University of Sussex,
Brighton BN1 9QH, UK (e-mail: h.e.dittmar@sussex.ac.uk). DOI:10.1348/000712609X484658
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 752 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
and disregard for financial constraints (Baumeister, 2002; Dittmar, 2001; Verplanken &
Herabadi, 2001). We thus use the traditional definition of impulsivity that emphasizes
lack of forethought and deliberation (Ainslie, 1975; Martin & Potts, 2009), rather
than referring to impulsivity in terms of impatience (Frederick, Loewenstein, & O’Donoghue, 2002).
Impulse buying is extremely common, with 90% of people making such purchases at
least occasionally (Hausmann, 2000), yet people often wish afterwards they had not
done so. In studies of impulse buyers, 80% were found to refer to some negative
consequences from their purchases (Rook, 1987), and 55% explicitly reported regret at
least once in a purchase diary (Dittmar, 2001). The near ubiquity combined with the
potential negative impact of this behaviour highlights the need for a better
understanding of factors that impact consumer impulsivity.
Individuals are not, however, impulsive all the time or with respect to all the
decisions they make, but this is something not well-explained by traditional
perspectives in decision making and microeconomics. We have no systematic
explanation of the fact that, typically, impulse purchases tend to be made for some
types of consumer goods, such as fashionable clothes, rather than others, such as basic
body care products (e.g., Dittmar, 2001).
We propose to examine three predictors of consumers’ impulsivity, all linked to
identity, defined as the subjective concept (or representation) that a person holds of
her- or himself (Vignoles, Regalia, Manzi, Golledge, & Scabini, 2006). The first
predictor is type of consumer good. People are typically more psychologically invested
in material goods that offer a high potential for the expression and communication
of identity than goods that are purely or mainly functional (Csikszentmihalyi &
Rochberg-Halton, 1981; Dittmar, 1992, 2008, in press; Kamptner, 1991). We therefore
propose that goods high in identity-expressive potential are discounted more steeply.
The next two predictors are linked. One of these predictors, materialistic values, can
be defined as a ‘set of centrally held beliefs about the importance of possessions in
one’s life’ (Richins & Dawson, 1992, p. 308). Those who endorse materialistic values
believe that acquiring new material goods is vital, particularly goods that are
expressive of social status, fame, and image (Dittmar, 2008; Kasser & Kanner, 2004).
Implicit in this type of materialism is the assumption that material goods are a good
way of attaining a better, more positive identity – more status, more fame, and more
image – which should make the buying of identity-expressive goods particularly
important to those who, in addition to endorsing materialistic values, also have high
identity deficits. Identity deficits, the other predictor, are defined as the salience of
perceived gaps between a person’s actual self (how they are) and their ideal self
(how they would ideally like to be).
We use an adaptation of the matching technique in a temporal discounting paradigm
(e.g., Benzion, Rapoport, & Yagil, 1989), because it provides a useful quantitative
measure of the extent to which an immediate reward is preferred to a larger, but delayed
reward. This paper reports three experimental studies which test the proposed new
consumer impulsivity model. In line with recent challenges to the discounted utility
model (Frederick et al., 2002), the first experiment focuses on systematic differences in
discounting as a function of type of consumer good. The second experiment examines
individuals’ materialistic value endorsement and identity deficits as additional predictors
of discount rates, and the third demonstrates that an experimental manipulation of
identity deficits in materialistic individuals affects discount rates for a good with high identity-expressive potential.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 753
‘I want it and I want it now’: Previous theoretical frameworks
Consumer impulsivity is characterized by an immediate, strong desire for a particular
good, by a lack of deliberation and careful planning, and often disregard for financial
constraints and consequences (Baumeister, 2002; Dittmar & Drury, 2000). There is a
battle between self-control on one hand, and desire on the other: ‘The budget is tight,
the price is too high, the item is not desperately needed, and so the shopper should not
buy it. Ranged against these sensible concerns is a murky alliance of wants, impulses,
and emotions, all clamoring for the gratification of the purchase’ (Baumeister, 2002,
p. 670). Our definition of consumer impulsivity is consistent with traditional
approaches to impulsivity (Ainslie, 1975; Martin & Potts, 2009).
Both anecdotal and research evidence suggests that consumer impulsivity is strong
with respect to certain types of goods, such as fashionable clothes and accessories,
but not with respect to others, such as basic body care products or tools (Dittmar &
Beattie, 1998; Dittmar, Beattie, & Friese, 1995, 1996), yet traditional accounts in
microeconomics and psychology1 have tended to see consumer impulsivity as a general
overweighing of short-term gratification relative to longer-term concerns, irrespective of consumer good.
Consumer impulsivity is a problem for traditional microeconomic decision theory
because it implies time-inconsistent preferences that switch from ‘I want it now’ to
later regret, violating the central assumption of the discounted utility model that
individuals have a consistent and unitary rate of time preference according to which
they discount the value of all delayed events. One influential variation conceptualizes
intertemporal choice as the outcome of a conflict between different selves: a ‘myopic’
doer focused on immediate gratification and a ‘farsighted’ planner concerned with long-
term benefits. Impulse buyers are assumed to discount the future at too rapid a rate,
where the benefits of the desired object at the point of imminent purchase outweigh
the (future) problem of paying the bill (e.g., Strotz, 1956; Winston, 1980). This does not
explain, however, why discounting should be disproportionately high, or why and
when people shift between short- and long-term preferences.
Ainslie (e.g., Ainslie, 1975, 1992, 2005) has challenged the traditional model. He
argues that delaying rewards from the moment of choice causes them to lose
effectiveness, so that preferences between a small-early and larger-late reward switch at
some point. Hence, discount rates are delay-dependent and follow a hyperbolic
function. Although he does not explicitly refer to differential discount rates for different
types of consumer goods, his hyperbolic discounting model leaves open that possibility.
Recent work, similarly, has challenged the assumption of a ‘unitary discount rate that
applies to all acts of consumption’ (Frederick et al., 2002, p. 394), and a series of
experiments consistently shows that consumables, such as food or drinks, are
discounted temporally more steeply than money (Estle, Green, Myerson, & Holt, 2007;
Odum, Baumann, & Rimington, 2006; Odum & Rainaud, 2003). However, we still know
little about psychological factors that impact temporal discounting of consumer goods
(i.e., variations in discounting that are likely to reflect psychological motives; Frederick
et al., 2002; Green & Myerson, 2004; Loewenstein, Read, & Baumeister, 2003).
1 Consumer behaviour and marketing work on impulse buying has been descriptive and a theoretical, identifying factors which
increase unplanned purchasing, such as exposure to in-store stimuli (e.g., Abratt & Goodey, 1990), or developing lists of foods
and drinks most likely to be bought impulsively (e.g., Bel enger, Robertson, & Hirschman, 1978). This does not explain
underlying motives, nor predict beyond the particular goods studied, thus not offering predictions regarding temporal discounting.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 754 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Hoch and Loewenstein (1991) offer a reference point model where consumers imagine
themselves as owning the good before they actually purchase it, and hence experience
foregoing the purchase as a loss and therefore an additional cost. The probability of such
a ‘reference shift’ is affected by several factors, such as people’s evaluations of goods,
and hence impact impulsivity. In later work, Loewenstein (1996, 2000) focuses on
‘visceral’ influences that produce short-term increases in the attractiveness of certain
goods. Others have suggested that goods which are an investment, or which
complement an investment, may be discounted more steeply (Borghans, Duckworth,
Heckman, & ter Weel, 2008; Borghans & Goldsteyn, 2006). For example, if owning a
particular good helps people to study towards an important qualification, then that good
complements the investment in study, and will therefore have higher utility. However,
its utility in the future may not be clear to the individual since they cannot assess their
needs at that future date – a ‘lack of imagination’. Therefore, a good may not have a fixed
utility, but its utility may vary across time depending on an assessment of how it meets individual needs.
In our research, we focus on identity-related factors as a framework for
understanding characteristics of consumer goods and individual consumers that affect
temporal discounting. Identity, an individual’s subjective representation of her- or
himself (Vignoles et al., 2006), is multifaceted and, in addition to individual, relational,
and group levels of self-representation (Sedikides & Brewer, 2001), also includes
material goods as parts of individuals’ extended identity (Dittmar, 1992, in press). This
can be applied to within-individual variations, whereby individuals can be impulsive at
certain times, but not others, depending on whether goods are linked to identity or not,
and to between-individual variations, whereby some people are more impulsive than
others (i.e., those with stronger identity-related motives for material goods).
Traditionally, individual differences in impulsivity have been explained in terms
of impulse control and personality traits. The ability to delay gratification improves
with developmental stage (Mischel, Ayduk, & Mendoza-Denton, 2003), and can be
used as an individual difference variable to predict performance on certain cognitive
tasks (e.g., Baron, Badgio, & Gaskins, 1986). Supporting evidence shows that children
discount future rewards more steeply than young adults who, in turn, discount more
steeply than older adults (Green, Fry, & Myerson, 1994), suggesting that young people
commit more impulsive acts than do the elderly (Read & Read, 2004). Others have
conceptualized impulsivity as a stable personality trait and found that highly impulsive
individuals show higher discount rates than their less impulsive counterparts
(Ostaszewski, 1996). Verplanken and Herabadi (2001) showed that general impulse
buying tendency correlates negatively with conscientiousness and positively with
extraversion of the Big Five personality dimensions, as well as with arousal and hedonic
buying considerations (Herabadi, Verplanken, & van Knippenberg, 2009). Baumeister
and colleagues (Baumeister, 2002; Baumeister & Vohs, 2003; Baumeister, Vohs, & Tice,
2008) see individual differences in self-control failure as a powerful potential predictor
of impulsive purchasing. Hence, the common implication is that there are stable
individual differences in impulsivity which, presumably, should manifest themselves
across different types of consumer goods, in the sense that individuals who discount
more steeply than others for one type of consumer good, should also discount more
steeply for other types of goods.
These frameworks, however, need further development. None offers an account of
one of the most striking aspects of consumer impulsivity: why it is the case that certain
goods tend to be bought impulsively (such as fashionable clothes) whereas others
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 755
commonly are not (such as basic body care products). The traditional discounted utility
model would predict that temporal discounting is independent of type of consumer
good. Trait-based approaches predict stable individual differences in discounting: if
some people are more impulsive than others, then this general propensity should
manifest itself across consumer goods. In contrast, we propose a new model with three
identity-related predictors of consumer impulsivity.
A new model of consumer impulsivity
Our starting-point is that consumer impulsivity in well-developed mass consumer
societies such as the UK has to be understood in the context of the contemporary
sociocultural environment. An increasingly powerful context in which individuals
construct and express their identities is the material and consumer culture we live in.
Having the ‘right’ material goods has become vital to many, not so much because of these
things themselves, but because of hoped for psychological benefits, such as moving
closer to an ideal identity, creating a desired social image, and achieving positive
emotional states. One reason for this greater psychological significance of material goods
is that traditional, stable means of identity construction – such as community, class,
religion, family, or nationality – have become eroded, particularly in urban
environments, leading to an empty self (Cushman, 1990). Instead of being ascribed
by the kinds of contextual factors listed above, identity is increasingly achieved by
the individual her- or himself. An important element of such achieved identity is
the acquisition, ownership, and consumption of material goods, which are used
increasingly to symbolize to self and others who a person is, their actual self, and who
they would like to be, their ideal self (Dittmar, 2000, 2004a,b, 2008, in press). Our model
includes three identity-related factors that we test as predictors of consumer impulsivity. Types of consumer goods
We propose that goods which have high identity-expressive potential are more likely to
be bought on impulse than goods unlikely to serve in this fashion. Extensive qualitative
research, using a ‘favourite possessions paradigm’, analyses the reasons why people
treasure some of their material goods very highly (Csikszentmihalyi & Rochberg-Halton,
1981; Dittmar, 1989, 1992, 2008, in press; Kamptner, 1991). In these accounts, it
emerges that identity construction, expression, and maintenance are powerful
psychological determinants of why material goods are important to people, with
clothes emerging as a particularly potent identity-expressive type of good. This is further
confirmed in analyses of clothes as consumer goods to be bought, as well as goods
already owned (Dittmar, 2008; Solomon, 1985). For example, in a UK community
sample, adults rated the importance of motives for buying clothes as compared to basic
body care products (such as shampoo) when they buy these types of goods on impulse,
defined as ‘a “spur of the moment” decision in the shop’. Buying motives to obtain
psychological benefits were all higher for clothes, such as improving one’s mood or
increasing one’s status, but the difference was most pronounced on the motives for
identity expression and moving closer to an ideal self (Dittmar, 2008, pp. 56–57).
Thus, clothes should make more likely targets for consumer impulsivity than goods
that have less identity-expressive potential, such as saucepans, and this has been
demonstrated in earlier studies, particularly for women (Dittmar et al., 1995). In support
of our proposal that material goods with high identity-expressive potential make more
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 756 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
likely impulse buys than goods which do not offer such potential, we can draw on data
from our own previous research. In one study (Dittmar & Anderson, 2004), a sample
of adult employees rated different reasons why they buy and value four different
consumer goods. Means for the scale ‘express who you are, make you feel more like
your ideal’ are given in the first column of Table 1. We found that clothes have a much
stronger identity-expressive function than the other three types of goods, particularly
basic body care products and tools, with effect sizes ranging from .6 to .8.
Table 1. Identity-expressive function and impulse buying frequency of five types of consumer goods Impulse buying indexb Actual impulse buy frequency Identity-expressive functiona (among students) (per month)
(Dittmar & Anderson, 2004) (Dittmar et al., 1996) (Dittmar, 2005b) Clothes 5.0 2.13 1.57 Sports gear nac 2.09 na d Music items 3.4 2.12 e 0.39e Basic body care 2.7 2.34 0.34 Tools 2.0 naf nad
a Measured on six-point scales ranging from 1 not at al to 6 very much.
b Less negative numbers indicate relatively higher impulse buying frequency.
c This consumer good was included in the rating study.
d This type of good was not coded separately in the diary study.
e The apparent inconsistency between the index and actual impulse buy frequency is due to music items
being high-impulse goods among students, but not among older, general population samples.
f This type of good was not included in the study.
At the same time, we have data from two previous studies on how frequently these
goods are actually bought on impulse. In a study with students (Dittmar et al., 1996), we
collected indices that compare the reported frequency of buying a type of good on
impulse with the frequency of buying it in a planned fashion, such that the resulting
index varies from 2 1 to þ 1, with less negative numbers reflecting relatively greater
impulse buying. The means are given in the second column of Table 1 and show that
sports gear and clothes are types of good that, comparatively, are more likely to be
bought on impulse than basic body care products.
A third study demonstrates directly how often these types of goods are actually
bought on impulse. Respondents from a community sample completed ‘shopping
diaries’ for 1 month, recording all impulse purchases made (Dittmar, 2001, 2005b).
Clothes stood out as the single, most frequent impulse buy. Respondents bought clothes
significantly more often on impulse than basic body care items and music items (see the
last column in Table 1 for means). Taken together, the findings in the ‘favourite
possessions’ paradigm in conjunction with the data presented in Table 1 offer a sound
basis for concluding that clothes are a type of consumer good that fulfils a particularly
high identity-expressive function for individuals, and that is bought on impulse much
more frequently than goods with much lower identity-expressive potential, especially
basic body care products or tools. Thus, we expect that discount rates, and hence
consumer impulsivity, differ systematically with respect to type of consumer good. It has
not been examined previously whether identity-expressive goods are, in fact,
discounted more steeply than goods less likely to serve this psychological function.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 757 Identity deficits
Identity deficits or self-discrepancies (Higgins, 1987) are defined as the psychological
salience of perceived discrepancies between a person’s actual identity (how they are)
and their ideal identity (how they would ideally like to be). These should sensitize
individuals to the identity-expressive potential of material goods, as long as they view
material goods as suitable tools for improving one’s identity (Dittmar, in press). Identity
deficits are a psychologically uncomfortable state to be in (Gramzow, Sedikides, Panter,
& Insko, 2000), and individuals are therefore motivated to close or minimize their actual-
ideal self-discrepancies. Symbolic self-completion theory (Wicklund & Gollwitzer, 1982)
proposes that people make use of material goods, amongst other strategies, to
compensate for perceived identity deficits. Supportive evidence shows that business
students who lacked good qualifications, displayed more relevant material symbols,
such as an expensive watch, briefcase, or business suit, compared to students with
better career prospects (Wicklund & Gollwitzer, 1982). A later series of studies further
confirmed a compensatory relationship between increased use of material symbols and
lack of experience, expertise, or competence in occupational, domestic, or ideological
identity domains (Braun & Wicklund, 1989). Thus, identity deficits are seen in the
present research as a motivator of decisions aimed at reducing the gap between how a
consumer ‘is’ and ‘would ideally like to be’. However, in order for identity deficits to
impact consumer impulsivity, or discount rates, individuals need to believe that buying
material goods is a suitable compensatory strategy. In other words, it is a prerequisite
that consumers endorse a materialistic value orientation.
Endorsement of materialistic values
A person who endorses materialistic values believes that the acquisition of material
goods is a central life goal, a prime indicator of success, and a key to happiness and a
positive identity. The link between material goods and identity is a core feature of a
materialistic value orientation (e.g., Kasser & Kanner, 2004; Richins, 1995), and
materialistic individuals are particularly motivated to buy goods they think will bring
them closer to their ideal self (Dittmar, 2005a, 2007, in press). Thus, whether or not
individuals endorse materialistic values is important for consumer impulsivity because
materialism is assumed to channel an individual towards consumption as a compensatory
strategy to deal with perceived identity deficits. Indirect support for this proposal comes
from research that shows that individuals most likely to report excessive, uncontrolled
buying were both materialistic and high in identity deficits (Dittmar, 2004b). We propose
that endorsement of a materialistic value orientation is needed for identity deficits to
lead to impulse buying. For materialistic individuals, consumer impulsivity should be
greater, and hence discount rates steeper, the greater their identity deficits. For non-
materialists, identity deficits should not impact consumer impulsivity. Furthermore,
materialists’ impulsivity with respect to identity-expressive goods should be higher
when their identity deficits are made salient temporarily than when they are not. The present research
In order to test our three predictors of consumer impulsivity, we use a temporal
discounting experimental paradigm. The desire to have a consumer good right now,
rather than to have to wait, is a preference concerning outcomes separated in time,
which can be captured by a discount rate. Individuals would want compensation for
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 758 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
delaying a desired outcome, and the amount of compensation necessary for a given
delay, as a proportion of the initial value, is the discount rate. Thus, discount rates
measure the subjective ‘cost’ of delaying immediate gratification. In the matching
paradigm of intertemporal choice methodology (e.g., Benzion et al., 1989), respondents
match the utility of a good to be consumed now (e.g., £100) with a (larger) delayed good
of the same type in the future (e.g., £X 1 year from now), by setting X such that they
are indifferent between the two choices. An annual discount rate of 50% means that
a person demanded £150 as their ‘price’ to wait a year rather than receive £100
immediately. Temporal discounting offers an appropriate experimental paradigm within
which to study consumer impulsivity, since steep discounting would push the consumer
towards immediate gratification, and the link between discounting and impulsivity has
been made by Ainslie (2005) and in a recent review by Green and Myerson (2004).
Obviously, steep discounting does not invariably lead to impulse buying, as there are
further factors involved that could prove to be barriers, such as whether one is carrying
a credit card or not to make the purchase possible, but it is a cognitive decision
concerning the good which would push the consumer towards impulse buying.
Temporal discounting can be measured in ways other than the traditional compound
discount rate outlined above. One approach uses non-linear regression to fit a
hyperbolic discount function of subjective value (e.g., Green & Myerson, 2004; Rachlin,
2006). This method is not suitable for our data for two reasons. First, because we fix
current value (you can have £10 now) and ask respondents to set the point of
indifference for a specific delay (how much would you want in 10 days’ time), in effect
holding subjective value constant and getting people to vary the amount being
discounted. Second, the hyperbolic function fits badly at the individual level, especially
when there are limited data points (as in the present research), which led Myerson,
Green, and Warusawitharana (2001) to propose the area measure as an alternative.
Notwithstanding its many advantages, this is not as good a measure for the current
experiments as the discount rate, because we choose delays that are unequally
distributed over time, in order to capture the difference between very short time delays,
1 day or 5 days, and much longer delays, such as 6 months or 2 years. The differences
between the different delays affect the contribution of respondents’ judgments to the
overall measure, so that the area measure would predominantly reflect responses to long
delays, obscuring discounting at shorter delays. Yet, it is shorter delays that are of
greatest interest in the present research.
Three sets of discount rate predictions can be derived from our model of consumer
impulsivity. The first is that discount rates will differ systematically, depending on the
type of consumer good, such that rates are steeper for goods with high identity-
expressive potential (Studies 1–3). Second, discount rates for such goods will be related
systematically to a person’s stable identity deficits, but only if they endorse materialistic
values (Study 2). Third, and finally, making identity deficits temporarily salient for
materialistic individuals will increase their discount rates for a good that typically has
high identity-expressive potential (Study 3). STUDY 1
The two aims of this first study were to (a) test a methodological innovation that
makes it possible to adapt the matching technique of the temporal discounting
paradigm to the study of different consumer goods and (b) to provide an initial
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 759
demonstration that discount rates differ systematically, depending on whether goods
are seen as having high or low identity-expressive potential (see Table 1), thus
addressing the first prediction of our model.
This study adapts the intertemporal choice matching paradigm by using vouchers for
different types of shop, which sell either goods with high identity-expressive potential
(such as fashionable clothes) or goods not likely to be identity expressive (such as basic
body care items like shampoo or nail clippers). In a repeated measures experimental
design, respondents are asked to imagine a particular kind of shop and the goods it sells
as vividly as possible, and then match the value of a voucher to be consumed now (e.g.,
£50) with a (larger) voucher that can be consumed only after a specified delay (e.g., £X
in 5 days time) by setting X such that they are indifferent between the immediate and
the delayed voucher. Money was included in addition to consumer goods. In order to
check whether this voucher adaptation is successful, we also assessed two well-
documented characteristics of discount rates, magnitude, and delay effects (Chapman,
1998; Green & Myerson, 2004), where individuals’ discount rates are higher for smaller
amounts of money, and for shorter delays.
Thus, the first hypothesis for Study 1 (1a) concerns two commonly observed
properties of discount rates, drawn from the earlier literature, whereas the second (1b)
addresses the first prediction of the proposed model of consumer impulsivity.
Replicating commonly found properties of discount rates is important in order to
validate our adaptation of the matching paradigm from money to different consumer goods through vouchers. Hypothesis 1a:
Discount rates will show a magnitude effect (with smaller rates for larger
amounts of money), and a delay effect (with smaller rates for longer delays). Hypothesis 1b:
Discount rates will differ depending on the type of consumer good, such that
they are steeper for goods with high identity-expressive potential (clothes, sports gear) than for
goods low in that respect (basic body care products). Method Participants
The sample consisted of 100 undergraduate students at the University of Sussex (UK),
studying for a variety of degrees.
Stimuli, materials, and procedure
The task was presented on computer and participants were run individually. The
program started by explaining the matching task and presenting a trial item for a
consumer good not included in the study proper. After ‘Life often makes us choose
between something nice NOW, and something even nicer, but LATER’, the trial item ran as follows:
Imagine that you win a prize in a shop that sells shoes that you really like. The prize is a
voucher to spend £75 on shoes in the shop, right now. Think about all the shoes you could
buy. Imagine yourself wearing them, and how they would feel on you.
Now imagine that you could swap this voucher for a (more valuable) voucher for the same
shop, but that you would not be allowed to spend it for 3 weeks.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 760 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
How much would the bigger voucher have to be worth so that you didn’t care whether you
got the £75 voucher now or the bigger voucher in 3 weeks?
(Respondent asked to enter an amount in full pounds Sterling).
In addition to making the matching task as transparent as possible, the wording was
intended to increase experimental realism and keep the respondent’s interest by inviting
them to imagine themselves as vividly as possible inside the shop and using the goods in
question. As soon as the respondent completed the trial item correctly (by entering an
amount exceeding £75), they started on the study proper, which asked them about
money and three types of consumer goods: clothes, sports gear, and body care products.
The delays were 5 days, 1 month, 6 months, and 2 years, and the amounts used were £10,
£50, and £200. In total, each respondent made 48 judgments. The items were presented
in blocks, containing all amount and delay combinations for one particular type of good,
and the wording introducing each new type of shop was the same as that given for the
trial item (e.g., … sells clothes that you really like … imagine yourself wearing
them … ). The order of blocks, as well as amounts and delays within a block, were
randomized to counteract order and fatigue effects. After each item, respondents
entered the amount of money needed for them to wait in full pounds Sterling. Results
Discount rates were calculated, according to a standard formula (e.g., Benzion et al., 1989), as r ¼ ðv = d v0Þ1=d 2 1:
where vd is the amount of money that the respondent entered as a ‘compensation price’
for having to wait, v0 is the magnitude of the immediate (voucher) money value, and d is
the delay in days between the two. Responses that implied negative discount rates, in
that the delayed value was less than the immediate value, were dealt with in one of two
ways. Four respondents were omitted from the analysis for making more than five such
responses, on the grounds that they had either not understood the task or had
responded randomly. Other than this, such errors occurred very rarely (in less than 1%
of responses) and appeared to be errors in keying in the answer (e.g., £30 to wait 2 years
for an immediate £200 clothes vouchers, instead of £300); based on agreement between
two independent judges of the intended answer, their judgment was substituted for the
original response (in this case £300 instead of £30).
Overall, the discount rates we obtained typically were very high (particularly in
Study 2 reported later). However, the few studies that have used delays as short as ours
report comparable, or even higher, rates (e.g., Kirby, 1997). As in previous studies
(e.g., Loewenstein, 1988), the substantial positive skew of the response distribution was
normalized through natural logarithm transform. The log-transformed discount rates
were analysed by a 4 (three types of good and moneyÞ £ 3 ðmagnitude of
amountÞ £ 4 ðlength of delay) ANOVA with repeated measures on all factors, including
a trend analysis on amount and delay. We found significant magnitude and delay effects
consistent with Hypothesis 1a. Discount rates decline with increasing amount of money,
Fð1; 95Þ ¼ 969:29; p , :001; h2 ¼ :91, and they also decline steeply with delay length, p
Fð1; 95Þ ¼ 1; 471:31; p , :001; h2 ¼ :94. The interaction between amount and delay p
showed that the steepness of discounting curves over time is greater for smaller than
larger amounts of money, Fð1; 95Þ ¼ 75:53; p , :001; h2 ¼ :44. p
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 761
The role played by type of good was examined by three a priori orthogonal contrasts
with the first contrast central to testing Hypothesis 1b. Discount rates for the two types
of highly identity-expressive goods were compared with those for body care items. This
was followed by comparisons between the two identity-expressive goods, and between
money and the consumer goods taken together. Of central importance is the predicted
finding that discount rates differ significantly by type of consumer good,2 such that rates
were significantly steeper for the identity-expressive goods (clothes and sports gear)
than for non-expressive goods (body care products), Fð1; 95Þ ¼ 14:14; p , :001;
h2 ¼ :13. Geometric means of daily discount rates for these different consumer goods p
are shown in Figure 1. In addition, the results for the second contrast show that clothes
were discounted even more steeply than sports gear, Fð1; 95Þ ¼ 9:09; p , :01; h2 ¼ :09, p
whereas the third contrast comparing money with the average across the consumer
goods was not significant, Fð1; 95Þ ¼ :92; ns. Discussion of Study 1
The magnitude and delay effects replicate hallmark characteristics of discount rates
commonly reported in the literature (Frederick et al., 2002; Green & Myerson, 2004). This
lends credence to the validity of our adaptation of the experimental matching paradigm,
which used vouchers for consumer goods as a methodological innovation. The central
finding that supports the first prediction of the proposed model of consumer impulsivity
is the systematic difference in discount rates between different types of consumer goods.
Respondents demanded significantly more compensation to wait for goods high in
identity-expressive potential, compared to a type of good that does not offer this
potential. Clothes were the consumer good that was most steeply discounted. Thus, the
proposal that discount rates are dependent on the type of consumer good was strongly
supported, which suggests stronger impulsivity with respect to goods that have high
identity-expressive potential, and these also make typical impulse buys.
The finding of the expected differential discount rates for high- and low-
identity-expressive goods is encouraging, but confidence would be strengthened by a
replication, preferably in a non-student sample. Furthermore, assuming that the
differential discount rates replicate, the second prediction of the proposed model of
consumer impulsivity needs to be addressed: that discount rates for identity-expressive
goods are related systematically to consumers’ identity deficits, as long as they endorse
a materialistic value orientation. STUDY 2
This study had two aims. The first was to replicate the finding that discount rates differ
between consumer goods in a sample of adult consumers. Adult consumers are likely to
have higher incomes than students, more opportunities for impulse buying, and
possibly a greater diversity in terms of consumer impulsivity. The second aim was to test
whether discount rates can be predicted from individuals’ identity deficits, if they
endorse materialistic values. For materialistic individuals, but not non-materialists,
2 Two-way interactions between type of good and magnitude or delay, as wel as three-way interactions were significant, but
with smal effect sizes (largest h 2 ¼ :04, and more than half # :03). p h 2p
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 762 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond 4.5 4 3.5 3 te t ra n 2.5 Identity-expressive u Non-expressive isco d % 2 ily a D 1.5 1 0.5 0 5 days 1 month 6 months 2 years Delay
Figure 1. Discount rates of identity-expressive versus non-expressive goods at different delays (Study 1).
we expect that their discount rates increase as a function of greater identity deficits, but
only for goods classified as having high identity-expressive potential, such as clothes.
The specific hypotheses examined were: Hypothesis 2a:
Discount rates for the identity-expressive good, clothes, will be steeper than for
the less identity-expressive goods, body care products, and music items (replication of Study 1). Hypothesis 2b:
For the identity-expressive good, clothes, but not the other goods, discount
rates will correlate positively with the extent of a person’s identity deficits, but only if they endorse materialistic values. Method Participants
The sample consisted of 60 adult consumers, who had participated in a larger mail survey
(Dittmar, 2004b, 2005b). They volunteered to take part in this study as part of several
follow-up investigations, for which they received a payment of £10. In terms of consumer
behaviour, the sample was heterogeneous, including some individuals who had contacted
a self-help organization because they lacked self-control in their buying behaviour.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 763
Stimuli, materials, and procedure
This study was also computer-run and very similar to Study 1. In addition to money,
clothes and body care products were examined as high- and low-identity-expressive
goods, respectively, as in Study 1, but music items were included as a second good
comparatively low on identity expression potential among this older community
sample. The amounts of voucher money remained the same – £10, £50, and £200 – but
we decided to add an unusually short delay 2 1 day – in order to be able to tap into
extreme consumer impulsivity that may manifest itself most strongly for a very short
time horizon. In order to keep the length of the experiment manageable, we deleted the
2-year delay used in Study 1, leaving four delays: 1 day, 5 days, 1 month, and 6 months.
Again, items were presented in blocks comprising all amount and delay combinations
for one particular type of good, randomized to counteract order and fatigue effects. Each
respondent made 48 judgments in total, completing the experiment in their own home
on a laptop computer brought by the researcher. They were asked afterwards to
comment on their experience of the discounting task.
Respondents’ identity deficits and materialistic values had been measured in the
larger mail survey in which these respondents had already participated (Dittmar,
2005a,b). We used our own measure of identity deficits, first described in Dittmar et al.
(1996), validated in Halliwell and Dittmar (2006), and discussed in detail in Dittmar
(2008, in press). It consists of a participant-generated self-discrepancy index (SDI),
which asks respondents to complete up to five sentences, of the format ‘I … … … , but I
would like … … ,’ using any word or set of words they liked, and then to rate each self-
discrepancy they generate in terms of its magnitude (size of discrepancy) and
psychological importance (concern or worry about the discrepancy), using five-point
Likert type scales ranging from not at all (1) to very much (5). As a global measure of
identity deficits, SDI is calculated by summing the products of the magnitude and
importance ratings of each self-discrepancy and then dividing by the number of
statements (Dittmar, in press). Thus, X h i =n; SDI ¼ I £ i D
where Ii is the importance of attribute i, Di is the distance between actual and ideal self
on attribute i, and n is the number of sentences completed. SDI scores could range from 1 to 36.
Materialistic value endorsement was assessed by an established and validated scale
(Richins & Dawson, 1992) that showed excellent internal reliability (a ¼ :87). Example
items are ‘One of the most important achievements in life includes acquiring material
possessions’ and ‘I would like to own things that impress people’. Using a criterion
score close to the theoretical scale mid-point (established in the full survey sample of UK
consumers, 2004b3), respondents were classified as either endorsing materialistic
values (n ¼ 39) or not (n ¼ 18). This means that those classified as endorsing
materialism on average agreed with the scale items, whereas those who were classified
as non-materialists on average disagreed with the scale items. We are aware that using a
continuous measure of a variable is usually preferred to a dichotomous split, but we
3 This survey had 330 respondents, diverse in educational qualifications, occupation, and income, thus offering a more
empirical y sound basis for classifying research participants as materialists or not than the smal er sample of respondents in the
present research, whose agreement to take part in fol ow-up studies is likely to indicate interest in consumption. The cut-off point
was both close to the empirical median split in the survey, 3.3, and to the theoretical mid-point of the materialism scale, 3.5.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 764 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
chose this strategy for two reasons. First, tests of interaction with continuous survey
measures, such as our materialism scale, often have less than 20% of the efficiency of
optimal experimental tests in detecting interaction effects (McClelland & Judd, 1993).
Second, our predictions are highly specific, such that we expect a positive correlation
between identity deficits and discount rates only in a particular subgroup of
respondents (those who can be said to have endorsed materialistic values) and for only
one type of consumer goods, clothes, which is unlikely to be reflected in an overall interaction term. Results
Log discount rates were calculated as in Study 1, and the very high discount rates for
short delays in the first study were also found here, particularly for the even shorter
delay of 1 day. The data of three individuals were omitted from the original sample of
60 according to the exclusion criteria employed in Study 1. The data were analysed by a
4 (three types of good and moneyÞ £ 3 (amount) by £ 4 (delay) repeated measures
ANOVA.4 Highly significant findings for the magnitude and delay effects again replicate
the commonly reported characteristics of discount rates also found in Study 1: steeper
discounting with smaller amounts, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 193:76; p , :001; h2 ¼ :78, with shorter p
delays, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 83:80; p , :001; h2 ¼ :61, and their interaction, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 7:87; p p , :01; h2 ¼ :13. p
The role of different types of goods was again assessed by three a priori orthogonal
contrasts similar to those used in Study 1. The first compared discount rates for the
identity-expressive good, clothes, with the less expressive goods, body care, and music
items. The second compared the two less expressive goods, and the third compared
money with all three consumer goods combined. Consistent with Study 1 and
supporting the first hypothesis, discount rates differed significantly by type of consumer
good, such that rates were steeper for the identity-expressive good than for the other
goods, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 12:83; p , :001; h2 ¼ :19. Geometric means are shown in Figure 2. p
The effect size was larger than in Study 1, and this may mean that adult consumers
discriminate more strongly between these different types of goods compared to
students. Music items and body care products did not differ significantly from each
other, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 3:12; ns. In contrast to Study 1, money was discounted more steeply
than consumer goods, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 13:65; p , :001; h2 ¼ :20.5 Thus, the central finding p
is that discount rates were higher for the type of good that has high identity-expressive
potential than for types of goods that are less expressive of identity. This provides
support for Hypothesis 2a and replicates the student results in this more heterogeneous adult sample.
We now turn to the second central question addressed in Study 2, which entails
a highly specific prediction of elevated discount rates. We expect that, for the
identity-expressive good, clothes, discount rates should be correlated positively with
the extent of a person’s identity deficits, but only if they endorse materialistic values.
4 Gender and whether individuals had been recruited via the buying behaviour self-help organization were also examined, but
did not yield systematic findings of interest for the present research.
5 In addition, two significant interaction effects were found for the contrast between goods high and low in identity-
expressive potential, showing that steeper discounting for short delays is amplified for identity-expressive goods,
Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 4:63; p , :05; h2 ¼ :08, particularly in conjunction with vouchers for a smal er amount, Fð1; 54Þ ¼ 6:36; p p , :05; h 2 ¼ :11. p
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 765 14 12 Identity-expressive Non-expressive 10 te t ra n u 8 isco d % ily 6 a D 4 2 0 1 day 5 days 1 month 6 months Delay
Figure 2. Adult consumers’ discount rates for identity-expressive versus non-expressive goods at different delays (Study 2).
For non-materialists, identity deficits should not be related to discount rates for this, or
any, type of good. Figure 3 shows the correlations between identity deficits and discount
rates,6 separately for materialists and non-materialists. For materialists, there was a
significant correlation, r ¼ :32, between their identity deficits and the discount rate
for clothes, whereas this correlation was close to zero for non-materialists, r ¼ :03.
Constraining these correlations to be equal in a two-sample structural equation model
resulted in a significantly worse model fit, Dx2ð1Þ ¼ 4:72, p , :01, indicating a
significant difference between them. As predicted, identity deficits were not signifi-
cantly correlated with discount rates for the less expressive goods, body care, and music
items, either for materialists or non-materialists. Thus, Hypothesis 2b was supported. Discussion of Study 2
Overall, the results of Study 2 replicated those of Study 1 with respect to discount rates,
and hence consumer impulsivity: discount rates were higher for a type of good that is
highly expressive of identity, clothes, than for less expressive goods. Findings also
6 The patterns of associations were similar in the different delay and amount conditions.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 766 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond Materialists Clothes .32** Identity deficits –.01ns Music items –.02ns Body care products Non-materialists Clothes .03ns Identity deficits .03ns Music items –.19ns Body care products ** p<.01
Figure 3. Correlations between materialists’ and non-materialists’ identity deficits and discount rates
for different types of consumer goods.
provide direct support for the proposal that discount rates for identity-expressive goods
can be predicted from a person’s materialistic value endorsement and identity deficits.
For materialistic individuals, higher identity deficits are systematically related to
demanding higher compensation for waiting to consume an identity-expressive good,
clothes, but not less expressive goods. As predicted, individuals who do not endorse
materialist values showed no links between discounting and identity deficits.
Possible criticisms of the discounting methodology we employed could be that the
task may be artificial, or that discount rates are not directly related to actual consumer
decision making in retail environments. However, the follow-up, where respondents
commented on their experience of the discounting task, showed that less than 4% found
the task boring or meaningless, and several respondents reported excitement, and even
physiological reactions, such as raised heart beat, confirming that our sample had
engaged with the task and took it seriously. More importantly, with respect to actual
decision making in shops, it was possible to calculate correlations between individuals’
discount rates for clothes and the frequency with which they had actually purchased
clothes impulsively in the previous month, as recorded in the separate shopping diary
study. Despite the short time span of the diaries (1 month), there are significant
correlations between respondents’ total number of impulse purchases of clothes and
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 767
discount rates at both 1 month’s delay, r ¼ :30; p , :05, and 6 months’ delay, r ¼ :33;
p , :05. Thus, there is good evidence that those who have higher discount rates in this
study are actually more likely to have made impulsive purchases of that type of good during the previous month.
Finally, this study examined identity deficits as a stable individual difference variable
and found, as predicted, systematic links for materialistic individuals between the extent
of their identity deficits and consumer impulsivity for a type of good that is typically seen
as offering high identity-expressive potential. Yet, perceived identity deficits can
fluctuate to some extent depending on context (e.g., Boldero & Francis, 2000; Dittmar,
Halliwell, & Stirling, 2009); people feel better about themselves at certain times and
worse at others. This suggests that implications of the proposed model could be tested
further through an experimental manipulation of temporary identity deficit salience. STUDY 3
Two main aims guided this final study. The first was to replicate again that there are
differential discount rates for different types of consumer goods. In this instance, we
decided to compare clothes, as a typical identity-expressive good, with a new low-
expressive good that may be more similar to clothes than basic body care products in
terms of unit price and likely time course of consumption. It was decided to use tools for
home and garden (e.g., tool kit, cordless drill) because tools are more costly than many
body care items and are consumed over a longer period of time, making them more
comparable to clothes on these dimensions. As already reported (see Table 1), tools are
not used for identity expression, in contrast to clothes. The second aim of this study was
to test whether a manipulation of the salience of materialistic individuals’ identity
deficits would impact on the discounting of identity-expressive goods. In the previous
study, perceived identity deficits were examined as a stable individual difference, but
they can also be examined as a temporary construct (Dittmar & Halliwell, 2005; Dittmar,
Halliwell, & Stirling, 2009). Such a conceptualization is consistent with evidence related
to self-discrepancy theory that shows that temporarily accessible constructs can have a
stronger influence on information processing than chronically accessible constructs
(Bargh, Lombardi, & Higgins, 1988). Asking respondents to list identity deficits can be
justified as a valid manipulation of their temporary salience, given that we have
demonstrated that completing the SDI leads respondents to focus on subjectively
meaningful gaps between their actual and ideal self (Halliwell & Dittmar, 2006).
Temporarily aroused identity deficits are a good predictor of momentary negative affect,
with negative affect a well-documented consequence of self-discrepancies (Dittmar,
Halliwell, & Stirling, 2009). Thus, we expect that heightened salience of identity deficits
would lead individuals to experience greater impulsivity, reflected by higher discount
rates for goods useful for expressing and improving one’s identity, provided they endorse
materialistic values and therefore use consumption as a deficit-reduction strategy.
Respondents for the present study were volunteers from the consumer panel of a
large, multinational manufacturer of consumer goods. The sample was women, with
clothes and tools as the two consumer goods examined, which differ strongly in their
identity-expressive potential (see Table 1). The salience manipulation of identity deficits
was simple and mild. Half the respondents were asked to complete the SDI directly
before the discounting task, and the other half afterwards. Thus, for half of the
respondents identity deficits were made salient when they considered compensation for
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 768 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
having to wait to obtain clothes and tools, but not for the other half. There were two hypotheses: Hypothesis 3a:
Discount rates will be higher for the identity-expressive good (clothes) than for
non-expressive good (tools), replicating Studies 1 and 2. Hypothesis 3b:
Making identity deficits salient will have a systematic impact on discount rates for
the identity-expressive good (clothes) compared to the non-expressive good (tools), but only
for materialistic individuals. Specifically, materialistic individuals are expected to report a greater
difference in discount rates between the clothes and tools when identity deficits are salient than when they are not salient. Method Participants
The sample consisted of 72 women who volunteered to take part in this study while
serving on the consumer panel of a multinational manufacturing company, half in the
high (n ¼ 34) and half (n ¼ 33) in the low identity deficits salience condition.
Stimuli, materials, and procedure
In order to enable data collection in the company, the discounting methodology had to
be adapted from being computer-run to questionnaire-based. Vouchers were valued at
£50 and £200 at each of four delays, 1 day, 5 days, 1 months, and 6 months, resulting in
eight items per type of good. Respondents considered one item at a time, which was
ensured through individual administration and concealment of later items. As in Studies
1 and 2, items were presented in a block for clothes and for tools and, within each block,
respondents completed the items in a fixed order (which had been randomly
determined). They then completed the same materialism scale as used in Study 2
(Richins & Dawson, 1992; a ¼ :72).
Half the respondents completed the SDI before the discounting task and half
afterwards.7 Thus, in the salient condition, they reported identity deficits directly
before discounting consumer goods, whereas they reported identity deficits afterwards
in the non-salient condition. Self-discrepancies were assessed as in Study 2, by the SDI,
that asked respondents to complete five open-ended sentences concerning aspects that
they would like to change about themselves, and then rate each self-discrepancy in
terms of its magnitude and importance. Results
Five participants were omitted from the original sample of 72 (see Study 1 for a
description of exclusion criteria). With respect to replicating the findings of Studies 1
and 2, discount rates were first analysed by a 2 (type of good ) £ 2 (magnitude) £ 4 (delay)
ANOVA with repeated measures on all factors. Magnitude and delay effects replicated
7 In order to make the two conditions more comparable, we included a further task that also involved participants in thinking
about the self, but would prevent them from considering shortcomings in their self-concept. Respondent simply wrote down
‘five things that you like about yourself ’.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 769
again, such that steeper discounting was found for the lower voucher amount,
Fð1; 66Þ ¼ 95:91; p , :001; h2 ¼ :59, and at shorter delays Fð1; 66Þ ¼ 32:53; p , :001; p
h2 ¼ :33. Of central importance is the significant main effect for type of consumer good, p
with discount rates steeper for clothes than for tools, as predicted, Fð1; 66Þ ¼ 13:10;
p ¼ :001; h2 ¼ :17. The mean daily discount rate for clothes was 1.09%, compared to p
0.84% for tools. Thus, the finding that a type of good that affords identity expression is
discounted more steeply than a non-expressive good replicated once again. The close
match between clothes and tools in unit cost and time course of consumption adds
confidence to the robustness of this effect.
In order to examine the effect of experimentally manipulating the salience of identity
deficits on discount rates, a single SDI score was calculated as in Study 2. There was no
systematic difference in SDI score between respondents in the two salience conditions,
tð65Þ ¼ 21:17; ns, thus excluding the possibility that pre-existing differences in identity
deficits between individuals allocated to the salient versus non-salient condition could
account for differences in discount rates.
In order to test Hypothesis 3b, which predicted an interaction effect between type of
good and temporary salience of identity deficits only for materialists, analyses were
run separately for individuals with (n ¼ 47) and without (n ¼ 20) endorsement
of materialistic values (using the same classification as in Study 2). Given our interest
in systematic differences, we analysed log-transformed discount rates (averaged
across magnitude and delayÞ £ 2 ðtype of goodÞ £ 2 ðsalience of identity deficits)
ANOVAs, with SDI as a covariate. In this way, we controlled for the extent of
individuals’ identity deficits, isolating the impact of the experimental salience
manipulation. The central concern of this study is to demonstrate that the impact of
identity deficits made temporarily salient on discount rates results in a significant
interaction between type of good and identity deficit salience, but only for materialistic
individuals.8 As expected, this interaction was not significant for non-materialistic
individuals endorsement, Fð1; 18Þ ¼ 0:11; ns; h2 ¼ :01. In contrast, the predicted p
interaction between goods and salience condition was significant for materialistic
individuals, Fð1; 43Þ ¼ 4:77; p , :05; h2 ¼ :10, and mean daily discount rates are shown p in Figure 4.
The means show that discount rates for the identity-expressive good, clothes,
increase to some extent when materialistic consumers’ identity deficits are made salient,
compared to when they are not salient. Although we did not necessarily expect that
making identity deficits salient would impact on discount rates for the non-expressive
good, tools, it appears they are lower after identity deficits are made salient. In other
words, identity deficits salience appears to lead materialistic consumers to differentiate
more strongly between goods high and low in identity-expressive potential. Indeed, a
test for simple effects shows that, whereas the difference in discounting between
clothes and tools did not reach significance in the non-salient condition,
Fð1; 44Þ ¼ 1:27; ns, it was highly significant when identity deficits are salient,
Fð1; 44Þ ¼ 44:24; p , :001. Thus, making identity deficits temporarily salient seems
to make materialistic consumers more inclined towards impulsivity for identity-
expressive goods, such as clothes, that are relevant to their ideal self, in contrast to less expressive goods.
8 Main effects for salience condition were not significant, neither for materialists, Fð1; 43Þ ¼ 0:07; ns;h 2 ¼ :00, nor p
non-materialists, Fð1; 18Þ ¼ 0:90; ns;h 2 ¼ :05. p
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 770 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond 1.4 Tools Clothes 1.2 1 % s te 0.8 t ra n u isco d 0.6 ily a D 0.4 0.2 0 IDs not salient IDs salient
Figure 4. Materialistic individuals’ discount rates for identity-expressive versus non-expressive goods by identity deficits salience. Discussion of Study 3
The differential discounting of goods high and low in identity-expressive potential
appears a robust finding, given that it was replicated again in this third study using a
different sample of adult consumers. The predicted interaction between type of good
and identity deficits salience for materialistic individuals provides further support for
the model of consumer impulsivity proposed. When materialistic individuals focus on
their identity deficits, they demonstrate significantly greater impulsivity for a good likely
to help them express or improve their identity than for a non-expressive good.
Moreover, this effect was demonstrated after a rather mild manipulation of identity
deficits: respondents had merely listed aspects of themselves that they would like to
change directly before the discounting task. Clearly, there are much stronger cues for
materialistic individuals’ identity deficits to become temporarily salient, such as
comments from family or peers, stimuli present in the shopping environment, or
possibly through social comparison with ideal models in the media (Dittmar, 2008; Richins, 1995). CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS
The three experimental studies reported provide good evidence for the first prediction
derived from the proposed model of consumer impulsivity. They demonstrate the novel
finding that discount rates differ systematically between types of consumer goods:
people are less willing to delay immediate consumption of goods that offer high identity-
expressive potential. The present studies, by necessity, examined a limited range of
types of consumer goods. Clothes are a typical good used for the expression and
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 771
improvement of identity across different age and social groups, whereas sports gear is
likely to be more identity-expressive on average among younger respondents, such as
students. Basic body care products, such as shampoo or nail clippers, do not offer much
by the way of identity expression or repair for any social group, whereas the non-
expressiveness of tools could be gender-related, being more characteristic of women
than men. Finally, the low identity expressiveness of music items is likely to be age-
related, given that music items appear to play a much stronger role for identity among
young, and particularly adolescent, people (e.g., Dittmar, Barker, & Bond, 2009;
Rentfrow & Gosling, 2003) than in our sample of middle-aged consumers. Clearly, goods
can vary in identity-expressive potential among different groups of people, although
clothes and body care items seem to be generally regarded as high and low in identity-
expressive potential. Ideally, a range of different consumer goods would be examined in
a single experiment, but given the maximum number of discounting decisions each
respondent could sensibly be expected to make without undue fatigue meant that not
more than three goods could be examined in any one study. Thus, future research may
wish to identify additional goods particularly high and low in identity-expressive
potential not examined in the present research. Moreover, it is possible that the goods
we studied vary on dimensions other than identity-expressive potential, such as unit
cost or time course of consumption, and further research may wish to address explicitly
whether such dimensions have an additional impact on discounting, or interact in some
way with identity-expressive potential. Yet, notwithstanding the need to examine a
greater diversity of types of goods, as well as additional characteristics of goods, steeper
discounting for identity-expressive goods compared to non-expressive goods was
replicated in three studies, with different samples, and using somewhat different
combinations of goods. This convergence lends strength to the potential generalizability of this finding.
In addition to predicting that type of consumer goods is an identity-related factor
that impacts impulsivity, our new model of consumer impulsivity predicts that
materialistic individuals’ identity deficits should be systematically linked to greater
impulsivity, but only for goods that afford identity expression. This prediction was
supported in Study 2 with respect to individuals’ stable identity deficits and in Study 3
with respect to the temporary salience of identity deficits. These findings, taken
together, support the interpretation that identity-seeking constitutes a novel, hitherto
neglected, but significant dimension of temporal discounting, and therefore consumer
impulsivity. Thus, the individual difference factors in the proposed model that
increase impulsivity constitute psychological motives that can be interpreted as identity-
seeking. Endorsement of materialistic values can be seen as a commitment to identity
construction through the symbolic potential of material goods, and identity deficits
consist of gaps between individuals’ actual and ideal selves that they are motivated
to close. Thus, materialistic individuals are motivated to move closer to their ideal
self through making use of material goods with high identity-symbolic potential.
In terms of theoretical implications, the proposed model is innovative in providing
an account of, and empirical support for, specific individual difference factors that
increase consumer impulsivity, all of which are related to identity.
From the perspective of economic theory, the point could be made that materialistic
consumers derive utility from discounting clothes particularly steeply if, indeed, they
can close, or minimize their identity deficits successfully when they by this type of
consumer good on impulse (e.g., Borghans et al., 2008). However, there are theoretical
reasons why this is unlikely to be the case: the pursuit of identity-expressive goods can
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 772 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
raise confidence or competence momentarily, but is not suited to solving the more
essential and common reasons for identity deficits, such as a lack of close interpersonal
relationships, community belonging, or a sense of meaning in one’s life (Dittmar,
Banerjee, & Bond, 2009; Vignoles, in press). Moreover, we have shown empirically in
shopping diary studies that, although the perceived boost in identity-related benefits is
greater in more materialistic individuals directly after the impulse purchase, it has
dissipated by the time people get home with their purchase – in contrast to less
materialistic consumers (Dittmar, 2001, 2008).
With respect to applied implications, the finding in Study 3 that identity-expressive
goods are discounted more steeply when identity deficits are made salient to
materialistic individuals raises the question of how malleable the perception of one’s
identity deficits can be, and whether impulse buying might increase when individuals
are made to feel bad about certain aspects of themselves. On the one hand, this raises
worrying implications from a consumer point of view, where marketers could decide to
deliberately devise in-store stimuli aimed at increasing consumer identity deficits.
Indeed, some would argue that this is already the case (Kilbourne, 2006). On the other
hand, it also offers an evidence-based foundation for consumer education, where
individuals, especially less experienced consumers (such as adolescents), could be
alerted to this link between identity deficits and impulse buying. The idea that consumer
education, as part of the school curriculum, can help guard against uncontrolled buying
has already been piloted in a European Union project (Garce´s Prieto, 2002).
Two areas of future research on materialistic value endorsement and identity deficits
as predictors of consumer impulsivity deserve particular mention. The first would be an
extension to impulsive purchasing in actual retail environments. For example,
individuals’ endorsement of materialistic values could be assessed and their identity
deficits made salient before they enter a shop or store, and then their purchases of
identity-expressive goods could be used to assess the impact of this field experimental
manipulation.9 Second, a dimension of consumer impulsivity particularly worthy of
future research attention is the disregard for financial constraints and consequences.
The model proposed here could be extended from discount rates to studying the extent
and frequency of individuals’ impulse buying over time as an outcome of type of good,
materialistic value endorsement and identity deficits, which in turn may be an important
predictor of individual personal debt given alarming debt levels in the UK (Creditaction,
2006) and other developed countries, particularly in the current global climate of credit
crunch (Creditaction, 2009). Given the increasing drive towards consumerism (Dittmar,
2004a, 2007, 2008; Kasser & Kanner, 2004), such an examination would be both timely and topical. Acknowledgements
The research reported in this paper was supported by Economic and Social Research Council
grant L122251012 as part of the Economic Beliefs and Behaviour Programme. Special thanks go to
Jonathan Baron, Graham Loomes, and Paul Sparks for their helpful comments on earlier versions
of this paper, to Peter Taylor-Gooby for his support and help as Programme Director, to Susanne
Friese who worked as research assistant on the project, and to Nick Anderson for his help with the
9 Such experimental work would, of course, need to be handled with great ethical care, but could also offer opportunities for consumer advice and education.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 773
data collection for Study 3. We would particularly like to acknowledge the invaluable contribution
of Jane Beattie (co-grant holder with H. D.), who conceptualized the first two studies reported and
worked on them until her tragic death shortly before the project ended. References
Abratt, R., & Goodey, S. D. (1990). Unplanned buying and in-store stimuli in supermarkets.
Managerial and Decision Economics, 11, 111–121.
Ainslie, G. (1975). Specious reward: A behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control.
Psychological Bulletin, 82, 463–496.
Ainslie, G. (1992). Picoeconomics: The strategic interaction of successive motivational states
within the person. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ainslie, G. (2005). Precis of breakdown of will. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28, 635–673.
Bargh, J. A., Lombardi, W. J., & Higgins, E. T. (1988). Automaticity of chronically accessible
constructs in person*situation effects on person perception: It’s just a matter of time. Journal
of Personality and Social Psychology, 55(4), 599–605.
Baron, J., Badgio, P., & Gaskins, I. W. (1986). Cognitive style and its improvement: A normative
approach. In R. J. Sternberg (Ed.), Advances in the psychology of human intelligence (Vol. 3,
pp. 173–220). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Baumeister, R. F. (2002). Yielding to temptation: Self-control failure, impulsive purchasing, and
consumer behavior. Journal of Consumer Research, 28, 670–676.
Baumeister, R. F., & Vohs, K. D. (2003). Sustaining delay of gratification over time: A hot–cool
systems perspective. In G. Loewenstein, D. Read, & R. Baumeister (Eds.), Time and decision:
Economic and psychological perspectives on intertemporal choice (pp. 201–216). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Baumeister, R. F., Vohs, K. D., & Tice, D. M. (2008). Self-regulation: Goals, consumption, and
choices. In C. P. Haugtvedt, P. M. Herr, & F. R. Kardes (Eds.), Handbook of consumer
psychology: Marketing and consumer psychology series (pp. 349–366). New York: Taylor & Francis/Erlbaum.
Bellenger, D. N., Robertson, D. H., & Hirschman, E. C. (1978). Impulse buying varies by product.
Journal of Advertising Research, 18, 15–18.
Benzion, U., Rapoport, A., & Yagil, J. (1989). Discount rates inferred from decisions: An
experimental study. Management Science, 35, 270–284.
Boldero, J., & Francis, J. (2000). The relation between self-discrepancies and emotion: The
moderating roles of self-guide importance, location relevance, and social self-domain
centrality. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 78, 38–52.
Borghans, L., Duckworth, A. L., Heckman, J., & ter Weel, B. (2008). The economics and
psychology of personality traits. Journal of Human Resources, 43, 972–1059.
Borghans, L., & Goldsteyn, B. H. H. (2006). Time discounting and the body mass index, evidence
from The Netherlands. Economics and Human Biology, 4, 39–61.
Braun, O. L., & Wicklund, R. A. (1989). Psychological antecedents of conspicuous consumption.
Journal of Economic Psychology, 10, 161–187.
Chapman, G. (1998). Sooner or later: The psychology of intertemporal choice. Psychology of
Learning and Motivation, 38, 83–113.
Creditaction (2006). Debt facts and figures – compiled 4th May 2006. Retrieved from
www.creditaction.org.uk/debtstats.htm
Creditaction (2009). Total UK personal debt. Retrieved from www.credit action.org.uk/debt- statistics.html
Csikszentmihalyi, M., & Rochberg-Halton, E. (1981). The meaning of things: Domestic symbols
and the self. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cushman, P. (1990). Why the self is empty: Toward a historically situated psychology. American Psychologist, 45, 599–611.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 774 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
Dittmar, H. (1989). Gender identity-related meanings of personal possessions. British Journal of
Social Psychology, 28, 159–171.
Dittmar, H. (1992). The social psychology of material possessions: To have is to be. Harvester
Wheatsheaf/St Martin’s Press: Hemel Hempstead/New York.
Dittmar, H. (2000). The role of self-image in excessive buying. In A. Benson (Ed.), I shop, therefore
I am: Compulsive buying and the search for self (pp. 105–132). New York: Aronson.
Dittmar, H. (2001). Impulse buying in ordinary and ‘compulsive’ consumers. In J. Baron,
G. Loomes, & E. Weber (Eds.), Conflict and tradeoffs in decision-making. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dittmar, H. (2004a). Are you what you have? Consumer society and our sense of identity. Psychologist, 17, 206–210.
Dittmar, H. (2004b). Understanding and diagnosing compulsive buying. In R. Coombs (Ed.),
Handbook of addictive disorders: A practical guide to diagnosis and treatment (chap. 13,
pp. 411–450). New York: Wiley.
Dittmar, H. (2005a). A new look at ‘compulsive buying’: Self-discrepancies and materialistic values
as predictors of compulsive buying tendency. Journal of Social and Clinical Psychology, 24, 806–833.
Dittmar, H. (2005b). Compulsive buying behaviour – a growing concern? An empirical exploration
of the role of gender, age, and materialism. British Journal of Psychology, 96, 467–491. doi:10.1348/000712605X53533
Dittmar, H. (2007). The costs of consumer culture and the ‘cage within’: The impact of the
material ‘good life’ and ‘body perfect’ ideals on individuals’ identity and well-being.
Commentary on Kasser, T., Cohn, S., Kanner, A. D., & Ryan, R. M. (2007). Some costs of
American corporate capitalism: A psychological exploration of value and goal conflicts.
Psychological Inquiry, 18, 1–9.
Dittmar, H. (2008). Consumer society, identity, and well-being: The search for the ‘good life’ and
the ‘body perfect’. In R. Brown (Ed.), European Monographs in Social Psychology Series. East
Sussex/New York: Psychology Press.
Dittmar, H. (in press). Material and consumer identities. In S. J. Schwartz, K. Luyckx, &
V. L. Vignoles (Eds.), Handbook of identity theory and research (chap. 31). New York: Springer. To appear.
Dittmar, H., & Anderson, N. (2004). Identity-expressive function of four types of consumer goods.
Unpublished manuscript, University of Sussex.
Dittmar, H., Banerjee, R., & Bond, R. (2009). Materialism and well-being: The role of perceived
peer pressure and identity deficits. Manuscript submitted for publication.
Dittmar, H., Barker, L., & Bond, R. (2009). Who is taking the rap? Correlational and experimental
associations between adolescent boys’ identification with rap music and their body
dissatisfaction. Manuscript in preparation.
Dittmar, H., & Beattie, J. (1998). Impulsive and excessive buying behaviour. In P. Taylor-Gooby
(Ed.), Choice and public policy (pp. 123–144). London: Macmillan.
Dittmar, H., Beattie, J., & Friese, S. (1995). Gender identity and material symbols: Objects and
decision considerations in impulse purchases. Journal of Economic Psychology, 16, 491–511.
(Also available on the world-wide web: http://www.ukc.ac.uk/ESRC/).
Dittmar, H., Beattie, J., & Friese, S. (1996). Objects, decision considerations and self-image in men’s
and women’s impulse purchases [Special Issue on Decision-making and Emotions]. Acta
Psychologica, 93, 187–206. (Also available on the world-wide web: http://www.ukc.ac.uk/ ESRC/).
Dittmar, H., & Drury, J. (2000). Self-image – is it in the bag? A qualitative comparison between
‘ordinary’ and ‘excessive’ consumers. Journal of Economic Psychology, 21, 109–142.
Dittmar, H., & Halliwell, E. (2005). The role of self-beliefs in women’s responses to idealised media
images. Funded by the UK’s Economic and Social Research Council’s (ESRC) grant RES-000-22-
0774. A research report detailing the main findings can be downloaded at www.esrcsociety today.ac.uk/ESRCInfoCentre
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society
Identity and consumers impulsivity 775
Dittmar, H., Halliwell, E., & Stirling, E. (2009). Understanding the impact of thin media models on
women’s body-focused affect: The roles of thin-ideal internalization and weight-related self-
discrepancy activation in experimental exposure effects. Journal of Social and Clinical Psychology, 28(1), 43–72.
Estle, S. J., Green, L., Myerson, J., & Holt, D. D. (2007). Discounting of monetary and directly
consumable rewards. Psychological Science, 18, 58–63.
Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference:
A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351–401. Garce
´s Prieto, J. (2002). Experiencias de trabajo en la prevencio`n y tratamiento de’ la adiccio `n al
consumo. In. I. Garcı´a Ureta & E. Olibarri Ferna´ndez (Eds.), El consumo y la adiccio `n a las
compras: Diferentes perspectivas (pp. 199–222). Bilbao: University of the Basque Country.
An English summary can be found in Nice-Mail, May 2000, News and Information about
Consumer Education, 13, 16-17 Last accessed 22nd December 2009 at http://www/info-
consumo.es/escuela/web/nice/eng/nice_13.pdf
Gramzow, R. H., Sedikides, C., Panter, A. T., & Insko, C. A. (2000). Aspects of self-regulation and
self-structure as predictors of perceived emotional distress. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 26, 188–205.
Green, L., Fry, A. F., & Myerson, J. (1994). Discounting of delayed rewards: A life-span comparison.
Psychological Science, 5, 33–36.
Green, L., & Myerson, J. (2004). A discounting framework for choice with delayed and
probabilistic rewards. Psychological Bulletin, 130, 769–792.
Halliwell, E., & Dittmar, H. (2006). The role of appearance-related self-discrepancies for young
adults’ affect, body image, and emotional eating: A comparison of fixed-item and respondent-
generated self-discrepancy measures. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 32, 447–458.
Hausmann, A. (2000). A multi-method investigation of consumer motivations in impulse buying
behaviour. Journal of Consumer Marketing, 17, 403–419.
Herabadi, A., Verplanken, B., & van Knippenberg, A. (2009). Consumption experience of impulse
buying in Indonesia: Emotional arousal and hedonistic considerations. Asian Journal of Social Psychology, 12, 20–31.
Higgins, T. (1987). Self-discrepancy: A theory relating self to affect. Psychological Review, 94, 319–340.
Hoch, S. J., & Loewenstein, G. F. (1991). Time-inconsistent preferences and consumer self-control.
Journal of Consumer Research, 17, 1–16.
Kamptner, N. (1991). Personal possessions and their meanings: A life-span perspective.
In F. W. Rudmin (Ed.), To have possessions: A handbook on ownership and property
[Special issue]. Journal of Social Behavior and Personality, 6, 209–228.
Kasser, T., & Kanner, A. D. (Eds.), (2004). Psychology and consumer culture: The struggle for a
good life in a materialistic world. Washington, DC: American Psychological Association.
Kilbourne, J. (2006, September). Jesus is a brand of jeans. New Internationalist, 10–12.
Kirby, K. N. (1997). Bidding on the future: Evidence against normative discounting of delayed
rewards. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 126, 54–70.
Loewenstein, G. (2000). Emotions in economic theory and economic behavior. American
Economic Review, Paper Proceedings, 90, 426–432.
Loewenstein, G., Read, D., & Baumeister, R. (2003). Time and decision: Economic and
psychological perspectives on intertemporal choice. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Loewenstein, G. F. (1988). Frames of mind in intertemporal choice. Management Science, 34, 200–214.
Loewenstein, G. F. (1996). Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational
Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 272–292.
Martin, L. E., & Potts, G. F. (2009). Impulsivity in decision-making: An event-related investigation.
Personality and Individual Differences, 46, 303–308.
Copyright © The British Psychological Society
Reproduction in any form (including the internet) is prohibited without prior permission from the Society 776 Helga Dittmar and Rod Bond
McClelland, G. H., & Judd, C. M. (1993). Statistical difficulties of detecting interactions and
moderator effects. Psychological Bulletin, 114, 376–390.
Mischel, W., Ayduk, O., & Mendoza-Denton, R. (2003). Sustaining delay of gratification over time:
A hot–cool systems perspective. In G. Loewenstein, D. Read, & R. Baumeister (Eds.), Time and
decision: Economic and psychological perspectives on intertemporal choice (pp. 175–200).
New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Myerson, J., Green, L., & Warusawitharana, M. (2001). Area under the curve as a measure of
discounting. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 76, 235–243.
Odum, A. L., Baumann, A. A. L., & Rimington, D. D. (2006). Discounting of delayed hypothetical
money and food: Effects of amount. Behavioural Processes, 73, 278–284.
Odum, A. L., & Rainaud, C. P. (2003). Discounting of delayed hypothetical money, alcohol, and
food. Behavioural Processes, 64, 305–313.
Ostaszewski, P. (1996). The relation between temperament and rate of temporal discounting.
European Journal of Personality, 10, 161–172.
Rachlin, H. (2006). Notes on discounting. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 85, 425–435.
Read, D., & Read, N. L. (2004). Time discounting over the lifespan. Organizational Behavior and
Human Decision Processes, 94, 22–32.
Rentfrow, P. J., & Gosling, S. D. (2003). The do re mi’s of everyday life: The structure and
personality correlates of music preferences. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 84, 1236–1256.
Richins, M. L. (1995). Social comparison, advertising, and consumer discontent. American
Behavioral Scientist, 38, 593–607.
Richins, M. L., & Dawson, S. (1992). Materialism as a consumer value: Measure development and
validation. Journal of Consumer Research, 19, 303–316.
Rook, D. W. (1987). The buying impulse. Journal of Consumer Research, 14, 189–199.
Sedikides, C., & Brewer, M. (Eds.), (2001). Individual self, relational self, collective self. New York: Psychology Press.
Solomon, M. R. (1985). The psychology of fashion. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Strotz, R. H. (1956). Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. Review of
Economic Studies, 23, 165–180.
Vignoles, V. L. (in press). Identity motives. To appear. In S. J. Schwartz, K. Luyckx, & V. L. Vignoles
(Eds.), Handbook of identity theory and research (chap. 31). New York: Springer.
Vignoles, V. L., Regalia, C., Manzi, C., Golledge, J., & Scabini, E. (2006). Beyond self-esteem:
The influence of multiple motives on identity construction. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 90, 308–333.
Verplanken, B., & Herabadi, A. (2001). Individual differences in impulse buying tendency:
Feeling and no thinking. European Journal of Personality, 15, 72–83.
Wicklund, R. A., & Gollwitzer, P. M. (1982). Symbolic self-completion. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Winston, G. C. (1980). Addiction and backsliding: A theory of compulsive consumption.
Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 1, 295–324.
Received 17 May 2006; revised version received 30 November 2009